01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

15. Basic <strong>Index</strong> Number <strong>Theory</strong><br />

387<br />

(i) The computer chip revolution of the past 40<br />

years has led to strong downward trends in<br />

the prices of products that use these chips intensively.<br />

As new uses for chips are developed,<br />

the share of products that are chipintensive<br />

has grown, which implies that what<br />

used to be a relatively minor problem has become<br />

a more major problem.<br />

(ii) Other major scientific advances have had<br />

similar effects. For example, the invention of<br />

fiber-optic cable (<strong>and</strong> lasers) has led to a<br />

downward trend in telecommunications prices<br />

as obsolete technologies based on copper wire<br />

are gradually replaced.<br />

(iii) Since the end of World War II, a series of international<br />

trade agreements that have dramatically<br />

reduced tariffs around the world.<br />

These reductions, combined with improvements<br />

in transportation technologies, have led<br />

to a rapid growth of international trade <strong>and</strong><br />

remarkable improvements in international<br />

specialization. Manufacturing activities in the<br />

more developed economies have gradually<br />

been outsourced to lower-wage countries,<br />

leading to deflation in goods prices in most<br />

countries. However, many services cannot be<br />

readily outsourced, 45 <strong>and</strong> so on average the<br />

price of services trends upward while the<br />

price of goods trends downward.<br />

(iv) At the microeconomic level, there are tremendous<br />

differences in growth rates of firms.<br />

Successful firms exp<strong>and</strong> their scale, lower<br />

their costs, <strong>and</strong> cause less successful competitors<br />

to wither away with their higher prices<br />

<strong>and</strong> lower volumes. This leads to a systematic<br />

negative correlation between changes in item<br />

prices <strong>and</strong> the corresponding changes in item<br />

volumes that can be very large.<br />

Thus, there is some a priori basis for assuming<br />

long-run divergent trends in prices <strong>and</strong> hence some<br />

basis for concern that a Lowe index that uses a<br />

base year for quantity weights that is prior to the<br />

base month for prices may be upward biased,<br />

compared to a more ideal target index.<br />

45 However some services can be internationally outsourced;<br />

for example, call centers, computer programming,<br />

<strong>and</strong> airline maintenance.<br />

D.3 Young index<br />

15.55 Recall the definitions for the base-year<br />

quantities, q i b , <strong>and</strong> the base-year prices, p i b , given<br />

by equation (15.23) <strong>and</strong> equation (15.24) above.<br />

The base-year revenue shares can be defined in the<br />

usual way as follows:<br />

(15.47)<br />

pq<br />

b b<br />

b i i<br />

i<br />

≡<br />

n<br />

b b<br />

∑ pkqk<br />

k = 1<br />

s<br />

; i =1,...,n.<br />

Define the vector of base-year revenue shares in<br />

the usual way as s b ≡ [s 1 b ,…,s n b ]. These base-year<br />

revenue shares were used to provide an alternative<br />

formula for the base year b Lowe price index going<br />

from month 0 to t defined in equation (15.26)<br />

as P Lo (p 0 ,p t ,q b ) =<br />

n<br />

n<br />

b t b b 0 b<br />

si ( pi / pi ) si ( pi / pi<br />

)<br />

i= 1 i=<br />

1<br />

∑ ∑ .<br />

Rather than using this index as their short-run target<br />

index, many statistical agencies use the following<br />

closely related index:<br />

n<br />

0 t b b t 0<br />

(15.48) PY p p s si ( pi pi<br />

)<br />

( , , ) ≡ ∑ .<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

This type of index was first defined by the English<br />

economist Arthur Young (1812). 46 Note that there<br />

is a change in focus when the Young index is used<br />

compared with the indices proposed earlier in this<br />

chapter. Up to this point, the indices proposed have<br />

been of the fixed-basket type (or averages of such<br />

indices), where a product basket that is somehow<br />

representative for the two periods, being compared<br />

is chosen <strong>and</strong> then “purchased” at the prices of the<br />

two periods <strong>and</strong> the index is taken to be the ratio of<br />

these two costs. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, for the Young<br />

index, one instead chooses representative revenue<br />

shares that pertain to the two periods under consideration<br />

<strong>and</strong> then uses these shares to calculate<br />

the overall index as a share-weighted average of<br />

the individual price ratios, p i<br />

t<br />

/ p i 0 . Note that this<br />

share-weighted average of price ratios view of index<br />

number theory is a bit different from the view<br />

taken at the beginning of this chapter, which<br />

viewed the index number problem as the problem<br />

of decomposing a value ratio into the product of<br />

two terms, one of which expresses the amount of<br />

46 Walsh (1901, p. 536; 1932, p. 657) attributes this formula<br />

to Young.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!