01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Producer</strong> <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Index</strong> <strong>Manual</strong><br />

16.84 Theil (1967, pp. 136–137) proposed a solution<br />

to the lack of weighting in the Jevons index,<br />

P J defined by equation (16.47). He argued as follows.<br />

Suppose we draw price relatives at r<strong>and</strong>om<br />

in such a way that each dollar of revenue in the<br />

base period has an equal chance of being selected.<br />

Then the probability that we will draw the ith price<br />

n<br />

i i i k k<br />

k = 1<br />

relative is equal to s 0 ≡ pq 0 0 ∑ pq<br />

0 0 , the period<br />

0 revenue share for product i. Then the overall<br />

mean (period 0 weighted) logarithmic price change<br />

n<br />

is ∑ s 0 ln ( 1 0<br />

i<br />

pi pi<br />

)<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

. 53 Now repeat the above mental<br />

experiment <strong>and</strong> draw price relatives at r<strong>and</strong>om in<br />

such a way that each dollar of revenue in period 1<br />

has an equal probability of being selected. This<br />

leads to the overall mean (period 1 weighted) loga-<br />

n<br />

rithmic price change of ∑ s 1 ln ( 1 0<br />

i<br />

pi pi<br />

)<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

. 54 Each of<br />

these measures of overall logarithmic price change<br />

seems equally valid, so we could argue for taking a<br />

symmetric average of the two measures in order to<br />

obtain a final single measure of overall logarithmic<br />

price change. Theil 55 argued that a nice, symmetric<br />

index number formula can be obtained if the probability<br />

of selection for the nth price relative is<br />

made equal to the arithmetic average of the period<br />

0 <strong>and</strong> 1 revenue shares for product n. Using these<br />

probabilities of selection, Theil’s final measure of<br />

overall logarithmic price change was<br />

(16.48)<br />

n<br />

1<br />

0 1 0 1 0 1 i<br />

ln PT( p , p , q , q ) ≡ ∑ ( si + si)ln( ).<br />

0<br />

i=<br />

1 2 pi<br />

53 In Chapter 19, this index will be called the geometric<br />

Laspeyres index, P GL . Vartia (1978, p. 272) referred to this<br />

index as the logarithmic Laspeyres index. Yet another<br />

name for the index is the base weighted geometric index.<br />

54 In Chapter 19, this index will be called the geometric<br />

Paasche index, P GP . Vartia (1978, p. 272) referred to this<br />

index as the logarithmic Paasche index. Yet another name<br />

for the index is the current period weighted geometric index.<br />

55 “The price index number defined in (1.8) <strong>and</strong> (1.9)<br />

uses the n individual logarithmic price differences as the<br />

basic ingredients. They are combined linearly by means of<br />

a two stage r<strong>and</strong>om selection procedure: First, we give each<br />

region the same chance ½ of being selected, <strong>and</strong> second,<br />

we give each dollar spent in the selected region the same<br />

chance (1/m a or 1/m b ) of being drawn. (Henri Theil, 1967,<br />

p. 138).<br />

1<br />

p<br />

Note that the index P T defined by equation (16.48)<br />

is equal to the Törnqvist index defined by equation<br />

(15.81) in Chapter 15.<br />

16.85 A statistical interpretation of the righth<strong>and</strong><br />

side of equation (16.48) can be given. Define<br />

the ith logarithmic price ratio r i by:<br />

(16.49)<br />

p<br />

ri<br />

≡ ln( ) for i = 1,..., n.<br />

p<br />

1<br />

i<br />

0<br />

i<br />

Now define the discrete r<strong>and</strong>om variable—we will<br />

call it R—as the r<strong>and</strong>om variable that can take on<br />

the values r i with probabilities ρ i ≡ (1/2)[ s i 0 + s i 1 ]<br />

for i = 1,…,n. Note that since each set of revenue<br />

shares, s i 0 <strong>and</strong> s i 1 , sums to one over i, the probabilities<br />

ρ i will also sum to one. It can be seen that the<br />

expected value of the discrete r<strong>and</strong>om variable R is<br />

(16.50) [ ]<br />

1 p<br />

E R ≡ ρ r = ( s + s )ln( )<br />

n<br />

n<br />

1<br />

0 1 i<br />

∑ i i ∑ i i 0<br />

i= 1 i=<br />

1 2 pi<br />

0 1 0 1<br />

PT<br />

p p q q<br />

= ln ( , , , ) .<br />

Thus, the logarithm of the index P T can be interpreted<br />

as the expected value of the distribution of<br />

the logarithmic price ratios in the domain of definition<br />

under consideration, where the n discrete<br />

price ratios in this domain of definition are<br />

weighted according to Theil’s probability weights,<br />

ρ i ≡ (1/2)[ s i 0 + s i 1 ] for i = 1,…,n.<br />

16.86 Taking antilogs of both sides of equation<br />

(16.48), the Törnqvist (1936, 1937) Theil price index,<br />

P T , is obtained. 56 This index number formula<br />

has a number of good properties. In particular, P T<br />

satisfies the proportionality in current prices test<br />

(T5) <strong>and</strong> the time reversal test (T11) discussed in<br />

Section C. These two tests can be used to justify<br />

Theil’s (arithmetic) method of forming an average<br />

of the two sets of revenue shares in order to obtain<br />

his probability weights, ρ i ≡ (1/2)[ s i 0 + s i 1 ] for i =<br />

1,…,n. Consider the following symmetric mean<br />

class of logarithmic index number formulas:<br />

56 The sampling bias problem studied by Greenlees (1999)<br />

does not occur in the present context because there is no<br />

sampling involved in equation (16.50): the sum of the p i t q i<br />

t<br />

over i for each period t is assumed to equal the value aggregate<br />

V t for period t.<br />

420

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!