01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Producer</strong> <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Index</strong> <strong>Manual</strong><br />

Laspeyres <strong>and</strong> Paasche indices are equally justifiable,<br />

with the Fisher index having support on axiomatic<br />

grounds. If the conditional intermediate input<br />

cost function takes the form of a translog technology,<br />

the theoretical intermediate input price index is<br />

exactly given by a Törnqvist index, which is superlative.<br />

If separability is invoked, Fisher <strong>and</strong> Walsh<br />

indices are also shown to be superlative, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

three indices closely approximate each other.<br />

1.119 The third index is the value-added deflator.<br />

The analysis is based on the maximization of a net<br />

revenue function, a function that relates output<br />

revenue less intermediate input costs to sets of output<br />

prices, input prices, <strong>and</strong> given primary inputs<br />

<strong>and</strong> technology. The results follow those from using<br />

a revenue function for the output price index.<br />

Laspeyres <strong>and</strong> Paasche indices are lower <strong>and</strong> upper<br />

bounds on their respective theoretical value-added<br />

deflators, <strong>and</strong> a family of theoretical value-added<br />

deflators could be defined that lie between them.<br />

The Fisher index again has some support as a symmetric<br />

average on axiomatic grounds, although the<br />

Törnqvist index is shown, using fairly weak assumptions,<br />

to correspond to a flexible translog<br />

functional form for the net revenue function <strong>and</strong> is,<br />

therefore, superlative. This finding requires no assumption<br />

of the more restrictive constant returns to<br />

scale that are necessary for Fisher <strong>and</strong> Walsh indices,<br />

analogous to those for the output price index.<br />

F. Aggregation Issues<br />

1.120 It has been assumed up to this point that<br />

the theoretical PPI is based on the technology of a<br />

single representative establishment. Chapter 18 examines<br />

the extent to which the various conclusions<br />

reached above remain valid for PPIs that are actually<br />

compiled for industries or the overall economy.<br />

The general conclusion is that essentially the same<br />

relationships hold at an aggregate level, although<br />

some additional issues arise that may require additional<br />

assumptions.<br />

1.121 That there are three possible PPIs requires<br />

an examination of how they relate to each other. It<br />

is thus necessary to consider how the value-added<br />

deflator is related to the output price <strong>and</strong> the intermediate<br />

input price indices, <strong>and</strong> how the output<br />

price index <strong>and</strong> the intermediate input price index<br />

can be combined in order to obtain a value-added<br />

deflator. It is shown in Chapter 18 that when the<br />

Laspeyres output price index is used to separately<br />

deflate outputs <strong>and</strong> the Laspeyres input price index<br />

is used to separately deflate inputs—double deflation—at<br />

each stage of aggregation, the results are<br />

the same as when Laspeyres is used to aggregate in<br />

one single stage. The separate deflation of inputs by<br />

the input price index <strong>and</strong> outputs by the output price<br />

index make up the components of the doubledeflated<br />

value-added index. The same applies for<br />

the Paasche index. However, if superlative price indices<br />

are used, there are some small inconsistencies.<br />

It was noted previously that unlike superlative indices,<br />

Laspeyres <strong>and</strong> Paasche indices may suffer from<br />

serious substitution bias. They may add up, but not<br />

to the right number. A value-added deflator equivalent<br />

to the separate Laspeyres (Paasche) deflation of<br />

output <strong>and</strong> input indices is shown as a weighted<br />

“average” of the Laspeyres (Paasche) output price<br />

index, <strong>and</strong> the Laspeyres (Paasche) intermediate input<br />

price index, although the weights used to combine<br />

the input <strong>and</strong> output deflators are rather unusual.<br />

1.122 But how do we derive estimates of doubledeflated<br />

value added There is an equivalence between<br />

a number of methods. Using the product rule,<br />

a value ratio divided (deflated) by a Laspeyres<br />

value-added deflator generates a Paasche valueadded<br />

quantity index; or, correspondingly, a value<br />

ratio divided by a Paasche value-added deflator<br />

generates a Laspeyres value-added quantity index.<br />

An alternative approach yielding equivalent results<br />

is to take value added in, say, period 0 at period 0<br />

prices <strong>and</strong> escalate (multiply) it by a series of<br />

Laspeyres value-added quantity indices. The resulting<br />

series of value added at constant period 0 prices<br />

will be identical to the results from separately escalating<br />

the value of inputs <strong>and</strong> outputs by their respective<br />

Laspeyres input <strong>and</strong> output quantity indices<br />

<strong>and</strong> subtracting the (escalated) former from the<br />

latter. More usually, estimates of value added at<br />

constant prices are derived by deflation. Deflating a<br />

series of nominal current period value added by a<br />

series of Paasche value-added indices yields a series<br />

of value added at constant prices. This is equivalent<br />

to double deflation: the separate deflation of the inputs<br />

<strong>and</strong> output current period values by their respective<br />

input <strong>and</strong> output separate Paasche price indices,<br />

subtracting the former from the latter. Similar<br />

equivalence results can be found using the less<br />

well-known approach for a comparison between periods<br />

0 <strong>and</strong> 1 of deflating the period 1 values by a<br />

Paasche quantity index to provide a measure of current<br />

period 0 quantities at period 1 prices. These<br />

24

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!