01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

15. Basic <strong>Index</strong> Number <strong>Theory</strong><br />

389<br />

these circumstances. Hence with long-run trends in<br />

prices <strong>and</strong> very inelastic responses of purchasers<br />

to price changes, the Young index is likely to be<br />

less than the corresponding Laspeyres index.<br />

15.59 The previous two paragraphs indicate that<br />

a priori, it is not known what the likely difference<br />

between the Young index <strong>and</strong> the corresponding<br />

Laspeyres index will be. If elasticities of substitution<br />

are close to 1, then the two sets of revenue<br />

shares, s b i <strong>and</strong> s 0 i , will be close to each other <strong>and</strong><br />

the difference between the two indices will be<br />

close to zero. However, if monthly revenue shares<br />

have strong seasonal components, then the annual<br />

b<br />

shares s i could differ substantially from the<br />

monthly shares s 0 i .<br />

15.60 It is useful to have a formula for updating<br />

the previous month’s Young price index using<br />

only month-over-month price relatives. The Young<br />

index for month t + 1, P Y (p 0 ,p t+1 ,s b ), can be written<br />

in terms of the Lowe index for month t,<br />

P Y (p 0 ,p t ,s b ), <strong>and</strong> an updating factor as follows:<br />

(15.50)<br />

⎛ p ⎞<br />

PY( p , p , s ) ≡ s ⎜ ⎟<br />

⎠<br />

n t+<br />

1<br />

0 t+<br />

1 b b i<br />

∑ i 0<br />

i=<br />

1 ⎝ pi<br />

n<br />

= P ( p , p , s )<br />

Y<br />

∑<br />

0 t b i=<br />

1<br />

n<br />

= P ( p , p , s )<br />

Y<br />

∑<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

n<br />

∑<br />

0 t b i=<br />

1<br />

n<br />

;<br />

using equation (15.47)<br />

∑<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

s p p<br />

b t+<br />

1 0<br />

i<br />

(<br />

i<br />

/<br />

i<br />

)<br />

b t 0<br />

i<br />

(<br />

i<br />

/<br />

i<br />

)<br />

s p p<br />

p q p p<br />

b b t+<br />

1 0<br />

i i<br />

(<br />

i<br />

/<br />

i<br />

)<br />

b b t 0<br />

i i<br />

(<br />

i<br />

/<br />

i<br />

)<br />

p q p p<br />

⎛ p ⎞⎛ p ⎞<br />

⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟<br />

⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠<br />

n<br />

t t+<br />

1<br />

b b i i<br />

∑ pq<br />

i i 0 t<br />

0 t b i=<br />

1 pi pi<br />

Y<br />

( , , )<br />

n<br />

b b t 0<br />

∑ pq<br />

i i<br />

( pi / pi<br />

)<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

n<br />

0 t b ⎡ b0t t+<br />

1 t ⎤<br />

Y( , , ) ∑ i<br />

(<br />

i<br />

/<br />

i) ,<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

= P p p s<br />

= P p p s ⎢ s p p ⎥<br />

⎣<br />

⎦<br />

where the hybrid weights s i b0t are defined by<br />

=<br />

b t 0<br />

si ( pi / pi<br />

)<br />

n<br />

b t 0<br />

∑ sk pk pk<br />

k = 1<br />

; i = 1,...,n<br />

( / )<br />

Thus, the hybrid weights s i b0t can be obtained from<br />

the base year weights s i b by updating them; that is,<br />

by multiplying them by the price relatives (or indices<br />

at higher levels of aggregation), p i<br />

t<br />

/ p i 0 . Thus,<br />

the required updating factor, going from month t to<br />

month t + 1, is the chain link index,<br />

n<br />

∑<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

s ( p / p ), which uses the hybrid share<br />

b0t t+<br />

1 t<br />

i i i<br />

weights s i b0t defined by equation (15.51).<br />

15.61 Even if the Young index provides a close<br />

approximation to the corresponding Laspeyres index,<br />

it is difficult to recommend the use of the<br />

Young index as a final estimate of the change in<br />

prices going from period 0 to t, just as it was difficult<br />

to recommend the use of the Laspeyres index<br />

as the final estimate of inflation going from period<br />

0 to t. Recall that the problem with the Laspeyres<br />

index was its lack of symmetry in the treatment of<br />

the two periods under consideration; that is, using<br />

the justification for the Laspeyres index as a good<br />

fixed-basket index, there was an identical justification<br />

for the use of the Paasche index as an equally<br />

good fixed-basket index to compare periods 0 <strong>and</strong><br />

t. The Young index suffers from a similar lack of<br />

symmetry with respect to the treatment of the base<br />

period. The problem can be explained as follows.<br />

The Young index, P Y (p 0 ,p t ,s b ), defined by equation<br />

(15.48), calculates the price change between<br />

months 0 <strong>and</strong> t, treating month 0 as the base. But<br />

there is no particular reason to treat month 0 as the<br />

base month other than convention. Hence, if we<br />

treat month t as the base <strong>and</strong> use the same formula<br />

to measure the price change from month t back to<br />

month 0, the index P Y (p 0 ,p t ,s b ) =<br />

n<br />

∑<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

s p p<br />

b 0 t<br />

i<br />

(<br />

i<br />

/<br />

i)<br />

would be appropriate. This estimate of price<br />

change can then be made comparable to the original<br />

Young index by taking its reciprocal, leading<br />

to the following rebased Young index, 48<br />

P Y *(p 0 ,p t ,s b ), defined as<br />

(15.51)<br />

b b t 0<br />

b0t pq<br />

i i<br />

( pi / pi<br />

)<br />

i<br />

≡<br />

n<br />

b b t 0<br />

∑ pkqk pk pk<br />

k = 1<br />

s<br />

( / )<br />

48 Using Irving Fisher’s (1922, p. 118) terminology,<br />

P Y *(p 0 ,p t ,s b ) ≡ 1/[P Y (p t ,p 0 ,s b )] is the time antithesis of<br />

the original Young index, P Y (p 0 ,p t ,s b ).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!