01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Producer</strong> <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Index</strong> <strong>Manual</strong><br />

B.2 The Young index<br />

1.42 Instead of holding constant the quantities<br />

of period b, a statistical office may calculate a PPI<br />

as a weighted arithmetic average of the individual<br />

price relatives, holding constant the revenue shares<br />

of period b. The resulting index is called a Young<br />

index in this <strong>Manual</strong>, again after an another index<br />

number pioneer. The Young index is defined in<br />

Section D.3 of Chapter 15 as follows:<br />

substitution is less than 1, the covariance will be<br />

negative <strong>and</strong> the Young will be less than the<br />

Laspeyres.<br />

1.45 As explained later, the Young index fails<br />

some critical index number tests discussed in Section<br />

C of this chapter <strong>and</strong> in Chapter 16, Section C.<br />

B.2.1 Geometric Young, Laspeyres,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Paasche indices<br />

n<br />

b⎛<br />

p ⎞<br />

(1.8) P ≡∑<br />

s ⎜ where s<br />

0 ⎟<br />

i=<br />

1 ⎝ pi<br />

⎠<br />

pq<br />

t b b<br />

i b i i<br />

Yo i i<br />

≡<br />

n<br />

b b<br />

∑ pi<br />

qi<br />

i=<br />

1<br />

.<br />

1.46 In the geometric version of the Young index,<br />

a weighted geometric average is taken of the<br />

price relatives using the revenue shares of period b<br />

as weights. It is defined as:<br />

1.43 In the corresponding Lowe index, equation<br />

(1.1), the weights are hybrid revenue shares that<br />

value the quantities of b at the prices of 0. As already<br />

explained, the price reference period 0 usually<br />

is more current than the weight reference period<br />

b because of the time needed to collect <strong>and</strong><br />

process <strong>and</strong> the revenue data. In that case, a statistical<br />

office has the choice of assuming that either the<br />

quantities of period b remain constant or the revenue<br />

shares in period b remain constant. Both cannot<br />

remain constant if prices change between b <strong>and</strong><br />

0. If the revenue shares actually remained constant<br />

between periods b <strong>and</strong> 0, the quantities would have<br />

had to change inversely in response to the price<br />

changes. In this case the elasticity of substitution is<br />

1, for example., the proportionate decline in quantity<br />

is equal to the proportionate increase in prices.<br />

1.44 Section D.3 of Chapter 15 shows that the<br />

Young index is equal to the Laspeyres index plus<br />

the covariance between the difference in annual<br />

shares pertaining to year b <strong>and</strong> month 0 shares (s i b –<br />

s i 0 ) <strong>and</strong> the deviations in relative prices from their<br />

means (r – r i * ). Normally the weight reference period<br />

b precedes the price reference period 0. In this<br />

case, if the elasticity of substitution is larger than<br />

one, for example, the proportionate decline in quantity<br />

is greater than the proportionate increase in<br />

prices, the covariance will be positive. Under these<br />

circumstances the Young index will exceed the<br />

Laspeyres index. 9 Alternatively, if the elasticity of<br />

9 This occurs because products with the large relative price<br />

increases (r – r i * is positive) would also experience declining<br />

shares between periods b <strong>and</strong> 0 (s i b – s i 0 is positive), thus<br />

having a positive influence on the covariance. In addition,<br />

products with small relative price increases (r – r i *is negative)<br />

would experience increasing shares between b <strong>and</strong> 0<br />

(continued)<br />

b<br />

s i<br />

n t<br />

⎛ p ⎞<br />

i<br />

(1.9) PGYo<br />

≡ ∏ ⎜ 0 ⎟<br />

i=<br />

1 ⎝ p<br />

,<br />

i ⎠<br />

b<br />

where s i is defined as above. The geometric<br />

Laspeyres is the special case in which b = 0 : that<br />

is, the revenue shares are those of the price reference<br />

period 0. Similarly, the geometric Paasche<br />

uses the revenue shares of period t. Note that these<br />

geometric indices cannot be expressed as the ratios<br />

of value aggregates in which the quantities are<br />

fixed. They are not basket indices <strong>and</strong> there are no<br />

counterpart Lowe indices.<br />

1.47 It is worth recalling that for any set of positive<br />

numbers the arithmetic average is greater than,<br />

or equal to, the geometric average, which in turn is<br />

greater than, or equal to, the harmonic average, the<br />

equalities holding only when the numbers are all<br />

equal. In the case of unitary cross elasticities of<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> constant revenue shares, the geometric<br />

Laspeyres <strong>and</strong> Paasche indices coincide. In this<br />

case, the ranking of the indices must be:<br />

the ordinary Laspeyres ≥ the geometric Laspeyres<br />

<strong>and</strong> Paasche ≥ the ordinary Paasche.<br />

1.48 The indices are, respectively, arithmetic,<br />

geometric, <strong>and</strong> harmonic averages of the same price<br />

relatives that all use the same set of weights.<br />

1.49 The geometric Young <strong>and</strong> Laspeyres indices<br />

have the same information requirements as their<br />

ordinary arithmetic counterparts. They can be pro-<br />

(s i b – s i 0 is negative), thus having a positive influence on the<br />

covariance.<br />

10

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!