14.03.2017 Views

policymakers demonstrate

EwB_Final_WithCover

EwB_Final_WithCover

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

284 Paul Ekins, Paul Drummond, and Jim Watson<br />

Because natural capital has featured regularly in various definitions of sustainability<br />

and sustainable development, more attention has been paid to the<br />

concept as sustainable development has risen up the public policy agenda. In<br />

this context, considerable efforts have been invested in developing and making<br />

environmental indicators operational (discussed in Section 7.3.3).<br />

Weak and Strong Sustainability<br />

Environmental economics traditionally considers environmental resource<br />

scarcity as a Ricardian ‘relative scarcity’ issue, where biophysical constraints<br />

on economic growth may be overcome by incurring additional cost in the economy<br />

in the short-term (through investment in innovative technology) (Venkatachalam,<br />

2007). This derives from a view that human or manufactured capital<br />

can substitute almost entirely for natural capital and ecosystem services, leadingtotheweak<br />

sustainability conclusion that, as long as the total economic<br />

value of all capital stocks (natural, human and man-made) can be maintained<br />

in real terms, regardless of the distribution between the different types, sustainability<br />

is achieved. An important strand in the sustainability and sustainable<br />

development literatures has called these assumptions into question, particularly<br />

for natural capital. The idea of strong sustainability, more often espoused<br />

in ecological economics, considers that certain elements, aspects are characteristics<br />

of natural resources and the environment, such as uncertainty and the<br />

‘irreversibility’ of some phenomena (e.g., an extinct species cannot be recovered)<br />

(Pelenc and Ballet, 2015) mean that some kinds of natural capital, which<br />

has been called ‘critical’ natural capital (CNC) (Ekins et al., 2003) makes a<br />

unique contribution to welfare or has intrinsic value and therefore cannot be<br />

substituted by manufactured or other forms of capital.<br />

Despite the contrasting theoretical positions taken on these issues, there is<br />

increasing alignment on them in practice in the environmental and ecological<br />

economics literatures. For example, many environmental economists recognize<br />

issues of multi-functionality, irreversibility and uncertainties surrounding natural<br />

capital, and support the idea of maintaining the natural capital stock independently<br />

of man-made capital. Summarizing the literature on the debate between<br />

the validity of the weak or strong sustainability approaches, Dietz and Neumayer<br />

(2007, p. 619) list four reasons why the strong approach to sustainability<br />

may be preferred to the weak: risk and uncertainty, irreversibility, risk aversion<br />

and the ethical nonsubstitutability of consumption for natural capital. However,<br />

proponents of both paradigms appear to agree that it is unlikely to be possible<br />

to conclude which natural capital may be considered ‘critical’ over an indefinite<br />

time horizon (Illge and Schwarze, 2009). A key, long-standing question<br />

remains the extent to which these two concepts may be combined, and how,<br />

to be useful for policy-makers and other stakeholders. Numerous indicators<br />

and indices of sustainability exist, with varied approaches, producing equally

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!