14.03.2017 Views

policymakers demonstrate

EwB_Final_WithCover

EwB_Final_WithCover

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

340 Stef Proost and Jacques-François Thisse<br />

case, when trade costs fall enough, some firms choose to produce in the North,<br />

say rather than in the South in order to benefit from a lower marginal cost while<br />

maintaining a high volume of export. As trade costs keep decreasing, a growing<br />

number of firms choose to set up in the North where the marginal cost decreases<br />

further. Note that firms tend to gather in one region despite the fact that the two<br />

markets where they sell their output are the same size. What now drives firms’<br />

agglomeration is no longer the size of the product market but the endogenous<br />

level of agglomeration economies.<br />

But where does agglomeration occur? Will it be in the North or in the South?<br />

Consider an asymmetric shock that gives a region a small initial advantage. If<br />

this shock remains fixed over a long period, firms will attune their behaviour<br />

accordingly. The region benefiting from the shock, however small, will accommodate<br />

the larger cluster. Hence, regions that were once very similar may end<br />

up having very different production structures as market integration gets deeper.<br />

Once more, lowering trade costs drives the economy toward more agglomeration<br />

in one region at the expense of another.<br />

Are growing regional disparities necessarily bad in this context? The answer<br />

is no. A planner whose aim is to maximize global efficiency sets up more asymmetric<br />

clusters than the market delivers. To explain, at the first-best optimum<br />

prices are set at the marginal cost level while locations are chosen to maximize<br />

the difference between agglomeration economies and transport costs. In contrast,<br />

at market equilibrium, firms take advantage of their spatial separation to<br />

relax price competition and do not consider the positive externalities associated<br />

with their location decision. So the optimal configuration tends to involve<br />

a more unbalanced distribution of firms than the market outcome. If agglomeration<br />

economies become increasingly important in some sectors, their uneven<br />

geographical distribution need not signify a wasteful allocation of resources.<br />

On the contrary, the size of the clusters could well be too small. However, the<br />

region with the larger cluster benefits from lower prices through larger agglomeration<br />

economies, more jobs, and a bigger fiscal basis.<br />

8.3.3 The Core–Periphery Structure<br />

The mobility of capital and the mobility of labour do not obey the same rules.<br />

First, while the movement of capital to a region brings with it production capability,<br />

the returns to capital do not have to be spent in the same region. In contrast,<br />

when workers move to a new region, they take with them both their production<br />

and consumption capabilities (putting aside remittances). As a result,<br />

migration affects the size of the labour and the product markets in both the origin<br />

and the destination regions. Second, while the mobility of capital is driven<br />

by differences in nominal returns, workers care about their real wages. In other<br />

words, differences in costs of living matter to workers but not to capital owners.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!