14.03.2017 Views

policymakers demonstrate

EwB_Final_WithCover

EwB_Final_WithCover

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Fiscal and Monetary Policies after the Crises 445<br />

to lower the real interest rate through its effect on π t+1 , and to deflate the real<br />

value of outstanding debt. The effect of the latter is to reduce net savings incentives,<br />

and thus raise the natural rate of interest, relative to an inflation-targeting<br />

policy regime.<br />

Importantly, optimal policy in the Benigno et al. (2014) setting is qualitatively<br />

different from a case in which the natural rate of interest is exogenous,<br />

as in the original contribution by Eggertsson and Woodford (2003). There, it<br />

is best to promise above-target inflation after the exogenous negative shock<br />

to the natural rate (positive shock to β t ) has disappeared, but not before. This<br />

suggests some care should be taken in interpreting optimal policy results from<br />

papers that treat the natural rate as exogenous. Few observers would attribute<br />

the fundamental cause of Europe’s current weakness to a psychological shift<br />

in preferences towards saving – though higher net savings rates may have followed<br />

from disruption in financial and real estate markets. More work is needed<br />

to understand exactly what the mechanisms driving a reluctance of consumers<br />

to spend are, and how best to overcome them.<br />

10.5.2 The Possibility of Secular Stagnation<br />

Yet even when allowing for these richer explanations for ‘savings shocks’, there<br />

is a growing concern in the literature that an account of low equilibrium interest<br />

rates dependent on shocks to the natural rate is, by its very nature, too temporary.<br />

As highlighted above, the nominal interest rate has now been near zero for<br />

more than six years in the US and much of Europe, and for around two decades<br />

in Japan. It is extremely hard to account for such long-lasting episodes by reference<br />

to a transitory disturbance, whether a deleveraging process or a short-term<br />

shock to individuals’ willingness to save. The challenge that the incipient secular<br />

stagnation literature is attempting to meet is how to explain long-lasting<br />

liquidity traps. 35<br />

The central secular stagnation thesis is that a binding zero bound can be<br />

explained by long-term (‘secular’) downward pressures on the equilibrium real<br />

rate of interest, rather than transitory shocks. Among the candidate explanations<br />

for this downward trend are: (1) a lower population growth rate; (2) a permanent<br />

tightening of credit conditions; (3) a decline in the relative price of investment<br />

goods; and (4) a decline in the relative supply of safe assets. The paper by<br />

Eggertsson and Mehrotra (2014) treats the first three of these, whilst the work<br />

by Caballero and Farhi (2015) addresses the fourth. In both cases the modelling<br />

approach departs from the common assumption of infinitely-lived consumers,<br />

in order to allow for meaningful variations in consumers’ demand for assets<br />

over the life cycle.<br />

Eggertsson and Mehrotra (2014) consider a simplified economy in which<br />

individuals belong to three distinct generations: young, middle-aged and old.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!