14.03.2017 Views

policymakers demonstrate

EwB_Final_WithCover

EwB_Final_WithCover

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

430 Charles Brendon and Giancarlo Corsetti<br />

Government Expenditure or Taxation as an Instrument?<br />

Returning to the specific problem of providing stimulus at the zero bound, an<br />

insightful paper by Correia et al. (2013) suggests an alternative stimulus strategy<br />

to the use of headline government spending, based on manipulating consumption<br />

taxation. Their main argument relies on the observation that if consumer<br />

goods are taxed at proportional rate τt<br />

c in period t, the inflation rate in<br />

t + 1 will satisfy the following relationship:<br />

(1 + π t+1 ) = 1 + τ t+1<br />

c<br />

1 + τt<br />

c (1 + ˆπ t+1 ) , (10.8)<br />

where ˆπ t+1 is the rate of inflation in pre-tax prices. If the concern is that inflation<br />

in period t + 1 is too low to incentivize consumption at t, an obvious strategy is<br />

to raise τt+1 c<br />

c<br />

relative to τt . This strategy for escaping a liquidity trap had been<br />

previously advocated by Feldstein (2002) for the Japanese case. The contribution<br />

of Correia et al. (2013) has been to clarify that the policy can go all the way<br />

to eliminating the problems caused by the zero bound, provided there are appropriate<br />

offsetting changes in other tax instruments. Most notably this means a<br />

cut in the labour income tax rate, so that the overall tax burden on workers<br />

is unaffected. Importantly, an appropriately-designed policy of this form can<br />

be revenue-neutral – the cuts to the labour income tax and the increase in the<br />

sales tax offset one another. This seems a substantial advantage in the current<br />

European context.<br />

Yet it is vital to this argument that the correct tax instruments should be<br />

chosen, with the explicit aim in mind of generating future inflation so as to<br />

stimulate current demand. When taxation is used imprudently as a stimulus<br />

device, it could have very detrimental consequences – a point highlighted by<br />

Eggertsson (2011). Suppose that a government were to try to conduct fiscal<br />

stimulus by cutting the marginal tax rate on labour income, in an economy<br />

constrained by the zero bound and a high desire to save. The main consequences<br />

can again be understood through the Euler condition. For simplicity we can now<br />

revert to ignoring government spending in this condition, giving:<br />

u ′ 1<br />

(Y t ) = β t E t u ′ (Y t+1 ) . (10.9)<br />

1 + π t+1<br />

Suppose that the income tax rate were to be reduced in period t, and in all<br />

‘bad’ states of the world in t + 1 – symmetrically to the analysis of higher<br />

government spending above. In ‘good’ states at t + 1 outcomes would remain<br />

essentially unaffected: there is no change to the income tax rate, and desired<br />

savings are sufficiently low to keep the economy away from the zero bound.<br />

But in ‘bad’ states – where the desire to save remains high – the incentives for<br />

would-be workers to seek employment are higher than they would be without<br />

the tax cut. This is likely to put downward pressure on the real wage: the lower

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!