14.03.2017 Views

policymakers demonstrate

EwB_Final_WithCover

EwB_Final_WithCover

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Innovation and Growth: The Schumpeterian Perspective 45<br />

that outside financiers involved in frontier-innovation will ask for a higher share<br />

of upside revenues and also for higher control rights: hence the role of equity<br />

in financing frontier innovation.<br />

1.4.2 Competition Policy against Industrial Policy<br />

Should sectoral policies always be precluded if we (justifiably) believe in the<br />

virtues of competition for innovation-led growth? Our answer is that sectoral<br />

policy can be designed and governed in a way that reconciles it with the need<br />

for more product market competition.<br />

Indeed, the ‘pick winner’ objection against sectoral policy loses bite when<br />

vertical targeting is properly designed and governed: in particular, when: (i) the<br />

government chooses to pick activities, not particular firms: indeed, while governments<br />

and policy-makers do not have all the knowledge and wisdom needed<br />

for proper vertical selection, identifying activities with high growth potential<br />

is presumably easier than selecting individual firms 14 ; (ii) the criteria underlying<br />

the selection of activities are clear and verifiable: in particular, recent<br />

research 15 points at skill-intensity and the degree of product market competition<br />

as relevant selection criteria for vertical targeting; and (iii) the vertical<br />

interventions are properly governed: in particular, they should be governed in<br />

a way that preserves or even enhances product market competition in the corresponding<br />

sectors, and also in a way that guarantees exit from nonperforming<br />

activities.<br />

First empirical support for rethinking sectoral policy is provided by Nunn<br />

and Trefler (2010). These authors use micro data on a set of countries to analyse<br />

whether, as suggested by the argument of ‘infant industry’, the growth of<br />

productivity in a country is positively affected by the measure in which tariff<br />

protection is biased in favour of activities and sectors that are ‘skill-intensive’,<br />

that is to say, use more intensely skilled workers. They find a significant positive<br />

correlation between productivity growth and the ‘skill bias’ due to tariff<br />

protection. Of course, such a correlation does not necessarily mean there is<br />

causality between skill-bias due to protection and productivity growth: the two<br />

variables may themselves be the result of a third factor, such as the quality of<br />

institutions in countries considered. However, Nunn and Trefler show that at<br />

least 25 per cent of the correlation corresponds to a causal effect. Overall, their<br />

analysis suggests that adequately designed (here, skill-intensive) targeting may<br />

actually enhance growth, not only in the sector which is being subsidized, but<br />

also the country as a whole.<br />

More recently, Aghion et al. (2015c) argue that sectoral policy should not<br />

be systematically opposed to competition policy. They use Chinese firm-level<br />

panel data. More precisely, they use firm-level panel data from the Chinese

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!