12.12.2022 Views

BazermanMoore

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

116 Chapter 7: Fairness and Ethics in Decision Making

unfair. Consumers seem to grant special status to the manufacturer’s list price, even if

they do not expect to pay that amount. The list price acts as a critical anchor for assessments

of fairness. It is unacceptable to exceed that amount. Yet, there is no normative

basis for the manufacturer’s list price having this special value.

The pattern that emerges is that individuals are concerned with departures from

the status quo and that economically justifiable actions will often be perceived as unfair.

We seem to rely on list prices and current prices to set a reference point against which

we assess changes. When prices change, interpretations of fairness are clearly influenced

by the framing effects we discussed in Chapter 4. It is hard to argue that the

resulting fairness judgments are rational. Nevertheless, managers ought to be concerned

about the way their actions are likely to be perceived by employees, colleagues,

business partners, and customers.

Thaler (2004) documents multiple examples in which consumers allow their emotions,

rather than market forces, to decide what is fair. He cites a variety of examples:

Delta’s attempt to charge $2 extra per ticket for tickets not purchased on the Internet,

First Chicago’s idea of a $3 charge for doing business with a human teller, Coke’s development

of vending machines that change price based on demand level, and American

Airlines’ enormous bonuses to executives at the same time the company asked

union employees for substantial wage concessions. In each case, there was no evidence

that these actions violated market pricing. However, most of us sense intuitively that

these were bad business ideas because most people would perceive them to be

‘‘unfair.’’

When We Resist ‘‘Unfair’’ Ultimatums

Consider the following situation:

You are traveling on an airplane, sitting in an aisle seat next to an eccentric-looking woman

(Vivian) in the middle seat. Next to her, in the window seat, is a rather formal-looking

businessperson (Mark). About thirty minutes into the flight, Vivian interrupts you and

Mark. She explains that she is quite wealthy, that she becomes bored on flight, and that

she likes to pass the time by playing games. She then pulls fifty $100 bills out of her wallet

and makes the following proposition: ‘‘I will give the two of you this $5,000 provided that

you can agree on how to split the money. In splitting up the money, however, I will impose

two rules. First, Mark must decide how the $5,000 is to be split between the two of you.

Then, you [the reader] will decide whether to accept the split. If you do accept, then you

and Mark will receive the portion of the $5,000 based on Mark’s allocation. If you do not

accept the split, then you and Mark will each receive nothing.’’ Both you and Mark agree to

play the game. Mark thinks for a moment and then says, ‘‘I propose that the $5,000 be split

as follows: I get $4,900 and you get $100.’’ Now it is up to you: Will you agree to this split?

If you are like most people, you will probably reject this split. Why? Obviously,

rejecting such a deal is inconsistent with traditional notions of economic rationality,

because each party would be better off (þ$4,900 for Mark and þ$100 for you) if you

were to accept it. However, you might choose to reject this offer for a variety of reasons

that lie outside self-interested wealth maximization. Reasons for rejecting the $100

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!