12.12.2022 Views

BazermanMoore

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The Impact of Temporal Differences

When Emotion and Cognition Collide 87

One way to describe the behavior produced by internal conflicts is by applying the economic

concept of discounting, which states that any choice that involves a tradeoff between

current and future benefits should discount the future to some extent. For

example, a can of your favorite soda should be more valuable to you tonight than if you

were to receive it ten years from now, if for no other reason than you might not be

around to enjoy it in ten years. A rational decision maker would discount the future

using exponential discounting, which means discounting each future time period by the

same percentage. Say, for instance, that your chance of death is about 1 percent per

year. You might then discount the value of the soda by 1 percent for a delay of one year.

If you had been willing to pay $1 to receive it immediately, you would only be willing to

pay $0.99 now in order to guarantee delivery a year from now. To guarantee delivery in

ten years, you would be willing to pay $1.99 10 , or about $0.90.

By contrast, self-control problems such as procrastination, laziness, and addiction

can produce choices that reflect hyperbolic discounting. The intuition behind this

theory, first formally employed by Laibson (1994), is quite simple. Relative to the

present time period, we view all gains and losses in the future to be worth less than they

would be in the present. Returning to the soda example, a soft drink would be worth

subjectively more to you today than it would be tomorrow or ayearfromnow.Note

that the difference between getting it in 365 days or 366 days seems miniscule, while

the same one-day delay between today and tomorrow is likely to matter much more. As

O’Donoghue and Rabin (1999) put it, we are biased toward the present.

Milkman, Rogers, and Bazerman (2007) examined the temporal component of the

conflict between the ‘‘want’’ self and the ‘‘should’’ self in the context of movie rentals.

They found that when people are ordering movies that they will receive days later from

their online DVD rental service, they focus more on what they think they should see

(such as documentaries and art films). In contrast, once the movies arrive, the movies

that they want to see (such as comedies and action movies) are more likely than the

‘‘should’’ movies to wind up in the DVD player. As a result, ‘‘should’’ movies stay in

customers’ homes without being played significantly longer than ‘‘want’’ movies. Essentially,

when customers are making decisions about the future, they focus on what they

should do. But when making decisions in the present, they are more likely to do what

they want to do.

The same researchers (Rogers, Milkman, & Bazerman, 2007) examined ordering

choices in the context of an online grocery delivery service, in which customers place their

orders online, and the order arrives within a few days. In general, as the time between the

order and the requested delivery increases, customers spend a higher percentage of their

order on ‘‘should’’ items (such as vegetables) than on ‘‘want’’ items (such as ice cream).

Finally, Rogers and Bazerman (2008) explore the support that citizens have for

policies that pit what they think they should support versus what they want to support.

An example of this conflict is a gas tax, which most people do not want, yet believe that

they should support. Rogers and Bazerman (2008) find that support for such ‘‘should’’

policies goes up significantly if the policy will be implemented in the future rather than

immediately.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!