12.12.2022 Views

BazermanMoore

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

view the negotiation with a positive frame. This is tricky, however, since the anchor that

will lead to a positive frame for one negotiator is likely to lead to a negative frame for

the other. This suggests that when mediators meet with each party separately, they

need to present different anchors to create risk aversion in each party. Again, to affect

the frame, mediators also must emphasize the realistic risk of the situation, thus calling

attention to its uncertainty and leading both sides to prefer a sure settlement.

ESCALATION OF CONFLICT

Escalation of Conflict 171

Following decades of animosity, on March 18, 1990, baseball team owners and players

reached a four-year agreement to avert a strike that had threatened to cancel the 1990

baseball season. The agreement expired on December 31, 1993, and the 1994 baseball

season began without a new contract in place. The first offer came from the owners on

June 14, 1994, but it was well outside the bargaining range. Dysfunctional bargaining

ensued, and on August 12, the players went on strike. 1

The strike effectively ended the 1994 baseball season and destroyed approximately

$1 billion worth of financial opportunity for the owners and players. Food vendors, retailers,

baseball card companies, and fans also suffered in various ways during the

strike. The strike’s inefficiency was highlighted when the courts required the team owners

to accept the preexisting structure for the 1995 season while negotiations for the

future continued.

From 1986 to 1993, Major League Baseball operated at a profit; by 1993, annual

profits had risen to $36 million. The strike changed that picture. The owners lost

$375 million in 1994, $326 million in 1995, and between $100 million and $200 million

in 1996 (Grabiner, 1996). Meanwhile, players lost money, status, and bargaining power.

For at least several years, baseball’s position as America’s national pastime was

tarnished. The strike was an extremely costly and vivid example of a conflict that

entered an escalatory spiral.

In the midst of the controversy, Sebenius and Wheeler (1994) offered a potentially

advantageous strategy for resolving the disagreement: Continue the baseball season,

but do not allow the teams to receive revenue or the players to receive their pay.

Rather, revenues and forgone pay would go into a pool until a resolution was reached.

In the meantime, watching the funds pile up would be an impetus for both sides to

agree on a settlement. Sebenius and Wheeler further argued that the parties could set

aside a portion of the fund for charity (such as the Special Olympics) if they failed to

reach agreement in a timely fashion—again encouraging compromise while creating

positive rather than negative public relations. Overall, Sebenius and Wheeler outlined

a very wise strategy that would have been far more efficient than the strike.

So, why didn’t the parties follow this advice? Our answer is that because each party

was focused almost exclusively on beating the other side, they were primed to escalate

their commitment to their initial course of action. One sign that the parties were

1 Many observations about the 1994 baseball strike in this section were prompted by the analysis of Chris

Maxcy, Lisa Mroz, Keith Rakow, and Cynthia Safford in a course assignment for the MBA negotiations class

at the Kellogg Graduate School of Management of Northwestern University.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!