12.12.2022 Views

BazermanMoore

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

academic programs, corporate battles for market share, and so on. Generalizing from

these objective win–lose situations, people form similar expectations for situations that

are not necessarily win–lose. When faced with a mixed-motive situation, such as a negotiation

that requires both value creation and value claiming, the claiming component

too often becomes salient, motivating most negotiators to develop a strategy for obtaining

the largest possible share of the perceived fixed pie. Such a focus inhibits the search

for creative solutions through mutually beneficial tradeoffs.

The destructiveness of the mythical fixed pie is captured in this Cold War–era declaration

by Rep. Floyd Spence, R-South Carolina, regarding a proposed arms reduction

treaty: ‘‘I have had a philosophy for some time in regard to SALT, and it goes like this:

the Russians will not accept a SALT treaty that is not in their best interest, and it seems

to me that if it is in their best interests, it can’t be in our best interest’’ (originally cited in

Ross & Stillinger, 1991). This kind of dangerously confused reasoning—that anything

good for the Soviet Union must be bad for the United States—defines the mythical

fixed-pie assumption. With the benefit of twenty-first-century hindsight, we can easily recognize

that treaties like SALT benefited both the United States and the Soviet Union by

reducing wasteful defense spending and the specter of nuclear war. And yet, Thompson

(2001) has found that even when two sides want the exact same outcome, such as ending

the Cold War, negotiators often settle on a different outcome or reach an impasse. The

mythical fixed pie can cause parties to fall prey to what Thompson calls the incompatibility

bias—the assumption that one’s own interests are at odds with the other party’s.

The mythical fixed pie also leads us to ‘‘reactively devalue’’ any concession made

simply because it is offered by an adversary (Stillinger, Epelbaum, Keltner, & Ross,

1990). In one study, Curhan, Neale, and Ross (2004) had negotiators estimate the value

of various possible outcomes before and after taking part in a negotiation. Negotiators

tended to like a possible outcome more after they proposed it in the negotiation. More

to the point, they tended to like a possible outcome less after it was proposed by the

other side. It seems that we are susceptible to viewing the same settlement terms as

advantageous when we propose them but disadvantageous when our counterpart proposes

them. As soon as the other party concedes on an issue, you might find yourself

devaluing the concession with this faulty logic: ‘‘If she is willing to make this concession,

the issue must not be very important.’’

When individuals make such assumptions about the other party’s interests, they

inhibit the search for mutually beneficial tradeoffs. The fact is, tradeoffs can be quite

easy to find when negotiators actively look for them. But when we ask business students

why they failed to make a tradeoff in a simulated negotiation, they commonly tell us

that they did not know that the tradeoff was possible. Why not? The fixed-pie assumption

prevented them from initiating the search.

THE FRAMING OF NEGOTIATOR JUDGMENT

Consider the following scenario:

The Framing of Negotiator Judgment 169

You bought your condo in 2005 for $250,000. You have just put it on the market for

$299,000, with a real target of $290,000 (your estimation of the condo’s true market value).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!