12.12.2022 Views

BazermanMoore

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

58 Chapter 3: Bounded Awareness

Radzevick and Moore (in press) observed a closely related effect in predictions

regarding the outcomes of athletic contests. They reasoned that if people focused on

their own team, they would be excessively confident of winning when their own team

was strong, regardless of the strength of the competition. Indeed, that is what they

found. Casino betting patterns suggest that people tend to bet on the home team primarily

when the home team is good. This effect is largely attributable to the fact that

people have better information about the home team than they do about the competition,

and they don’t bother collecting more balanced information before placing their

bets.

Moore (2004b, 2005) documented bounded awareness in the context of negotiation

deadlines. In a negotiation between a buyer and seller in which both parties get

zero payoff if no agreement is reached, a publicly known deadline on one of the parties

intuitively appears to put that party at a disadvantage. Of course, if one party has a

deadline, the other cannot go on negotiating without them. Objectively, the deadline

affects the two parties symmetrically, but negotiators fail to consider the deadline’s effect

on the other side, and so think that a deadline puts them at an asymmetric disadvantage.

Because they think that the deadline represents their own weakness, when

they have to decide whether they want to tell the other side about the time constraint,

most negotiators choose not to do so (Gino & Moore, 2008; Moore, 2004a). Ironically,

this does turn the deadline into a real disadvantage because the negotiator who knows

about it is hurrying to get a deal before the deadline, while the other side continues at a

more leisurely pace.

Massey and Wu (2005) have examined ‘‘system neglect,’’ or the human tendency of

people to undervalue the importance of the general context in which they are making

their decision. To us, the most important example of this type of bounded awareness is

the widespread failure of U.S. citizens to consider campaign-finance reform as a means

of curbing the undue political influence of special-interest groups (Bazerman, Baron, &

Shonk, 2001). When people are asked whether they support and care about the issue of

campaign-finance reform, they say, ‘‘Yes.’’ Yet, when asked to rank the importance of

campaign-finance reform relative to other issues, they rank it very low. Bazerman et al.

(2001) argue that voters undervalue campaign-finance reform because their awareness

of the indirect impact of campaign-finance reform is bounded. Yet, we believe that people

should care deeply about such reform, since it affects virtually every other issue

(and its effects could be enormous). People do not tend to think through this process.

They value issues that are more clearly seen as end states or outcomes (such as tax cuts

or education), rather than using a broader awareness that would direct their attention

toward a set of outcomes that would have a large, positive effect on many issues

(Bazerman, Baron, & Shonk, 2001).

Finally, bounded awareness can keep negotiators from considering the impact of

their decisions on others outside the negotiation. Decision and negotiation scholars

often study and teach cooperation in prisoner dilemma games and social dilemmas. A

prisoner dilemma game exists when two parties or more would be jointly better off both

cooperating with each other than both defecting (betraying each other), yet each party

would be better off defecting on the other, regardless of the behavior of the other party.

The prisoner dilemma problem has been used as a model to understand defection in

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!