30.04.2014 Views

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

H3: Buyer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> positively influences <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> more str<strong>on</strong>gly<br />

in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s than in the United States.<br />

Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Some aspects of an<br />

individual’s risk-taking behavior are influenced by their nati<strong>on</strong>al culture. One<br />

example of this is the popular cushi<strong>on</strong> hypothesis (Weber & Hsee, 1999). Individual<br />

investors take more risk if they feel that their collectivist society will take care of<br />

them if things were to go wr<strong>on</strong>g (Weber & Hsee, 1999). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in<br />

societies that are individualistic, investors will take less risk because no <strong>on</strong>e is there to<br />

bail them out in case things go wr<strong>on</strong>g (Weber & Hsee, 1999). Indeed, nati<strong>on</strong>al culture<br />

does matter when individuals are making decisi<strong>on</strong>s with regards to risk (Weber &<br />

Hsee, 1999). Nati<strong>on</strong>al culture also influences their risk preference. The Dutch shoe<br />

manufacturer Van Bommel is a case in point. They offer a fifteen-year guarantee with<br />

every high quality pair of shoes, yet they chose the slightly costlier opti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

producing in the UK rather than in China or Portugal, because of quality c<strong>on</strong>cerns <strong>and</strong><br />

risk avoidance. Many other high quality manufacturers do produce in Portugal (Zara)<br />

<strong>and</strong> China (Apple). But Van Bommel’s decisi<strong>on</strong> is a case of traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

manufacturers’ c<strong>on</strong>cerns leading them to what they perceive to be a safe decisi<strong>on</strong><br />

(Dys<strong>on</strong>, pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, 2010).<br />

As risk preferences vary across nati<strong>on</strong>s, it would follow in turn that customer’s<br />

risk preference would influence their preference of channel partners. Some managers<br />

may prefer riskier business partners because of the potential higher fluctuati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

profits. Others may want more stability in their earnings (Weber & Hsee, 1999).<br />

Although much research exists <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer br<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> risk preference<br />

(Erdem, Zhao, & Valenzuela, 2004; Mitchell, 1999), there is limited research in the<br />

B2B br<strong>and</strong>ing domain <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between B2B br<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> risk. Our literature<br />

search revealed limited evidence in the marketing literature available <strong>on</strong> risk-taking<br />

behavior, buying centers, <strong>and</strong> br<strong>and</strong> preferences. However, we did find <strong>on</strong>e B2B<br />

br<strong>and</strong>ing text that dealt with the issue by Kotler <strong>and</strong> Pfoertsch (2006, p.9). They<br />

indicate that B2B br<strong>and</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>ality is negatively related to customer risk. Therefore,<br />

we expect:<br />

H4: Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk negatively influences <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> in<br />

the USA <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Supplier br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. A <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is likely<br />

to have a spillover effect <strong>on</strong> a <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> future <strong>value</strong> if they add unique <strong>value</strong> to the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>. For instance, Ghosh <strong>and</strong> John (2009) found that the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> was<br />

more likely to be preferred in the future when the <strong>supplier</strong>’s comp<strong>on</strong>ents added<br />

unique <strong>value</strong> to the <strong>buyer</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>. Such unique <strong>value</strong> has a financial dimensi<strong>on</strong> for<br />

the <strong>buyer</strong> through increased marketplace performance. Intel is a stellar example of<br />

such a strategy, <strong>and</strong> it has a spillover <strong>on</strong> any product it is a comp<strong>on</strong>ent of (Whitwell,<br />

2005). C<strong>on</strong>sider NutraSweet, whose patent ran out but is still able to charge a<br />

premium for its br<strong>and</strong> because of the public c<strong>on</strong>fidence in NutraSweet. C<strong>on</strong>sumers are<br />

willing to pay more for products with NutraSweet logos or as an ingredient (Norris,<br />

1992). Other examples of <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> which add <strong>value</strong> to the customers br<strong>and</strong><br />

include Dup<strong>on</strong>t with nyl<strong>on</strong> for clothes, Rayth<strong>on</strong>’s Lycra <strong>and</strong> Good Year tires <strong>on</strong><br />

Adidas shoe soles. Harvard Business School professor Jack Quelch describes it best in<br />

a rhetorical questi<strong>on</strong>:<br />

82

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!