30.04.2014 Views

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

“It is <strong>on</strong>e of the comm<strong>on</strong>est of mistakes to c<strong>on</strong>sider that the limit of our power<br />

of percepti<strong>on</strong> is also the limit of all there is to perceive.”<br />

—C. W. Leadbeater (n.d.)<br />

"On the face of it, shareholder <strong>value</strong> is the dumbest idea in the world."<br />

—Jack Welch<br />

Former CEO, General Electric (Guerrera,<br />

2009).<br />

4.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

The financial crisis of 2009 is an example of the inc<strong>on</strong>gruence between subjective <strong>and</strong><br />

objective measurement. Prior to the financial crisis, many <strong>firm</strong>s had benefitted because of<br />

investors’ irrati<strong>on</strong>al exuberance about financial markets (Akerlof & Shiller, 2010). This<br />

benefit occurred even though many <strong>firm</strong>’s objective financial indicators did not reflect such<br />

exuberance. The outcome of the diss<strong>on</strong>ance between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measurement<br />

can be grave, as is illustrated by the large number of bankruptcies in 2009. Similarly, in the<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature, numerous studies have included objective <strong>and</strong> subjective or<br />

perceptual measures <strong>and</strong> have c<strong>on</strong>tradictory or different results (Jaworski & Kohli, 1993;<br />

Narver & Slater, 1990). We define subjective metrics as those based <strong>on</strong> managerial<br />

heuristics <strong>and</strong> objective metrics as those based <strong>on</strong> some externally verifiable accounting or<br />

financial procedure.<br />

All subjective or perceptual data are based <strong>on</strong> human percepti<strong>on</strong>s. Human<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong>s are notoriously fickle <strong>and</strong> not necessarily a representative of market realities<br />

(Cassidy, 2009, pp. 10-11). This is not because people or managers are irrati<strong>on</strong>al, but rather<br />

because their limited mental capabilities do not at times allow them to process all the<br />

complicated factors or indicators (Cassidy, 2009, pp. 10-11). Furthermore, managers 4<br />

usually <strong>on</strong>ly remember more recent events (Foer, 2011). This is a weakness when<br />

measuring <strong>supplier</strong> performance because the relati<strong>on</strong>ship is based <strong>on</strong> a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum of<br />

interacti<strong>on</strong>s, not just the most recent interacti<strong>on</strong>s. Tversky <strong>and</strong> Kahneman (1974)<br />

investigated heuristics or mental short cuts. The first mental short cut is representativeness,<br />

meaning that managers generalize with insufficient evidence (Cassidy, 2009, p. 195;<br />

Tversky & Kahneman, 1974). Even when experimental subjects were provided with<br />

statistical data to guide their decisi<strong>on</strong>s, they still jumped to c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s for which they did<br />

not have much evidence (Cassidy, 2009, pp. 195-196). This jumping to c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s also<br />

leads to the phenomen<strong>on</strong> of overc<strong>on</strong>fidence, which has led to many financial fiascos<br />

(Cassidy, 2009, pp. 195-196). Managers who are overc<strong>on</strong>fident take short-term relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

trends with strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s as indicators of the l<strong>on</strong>g-term trends. This overc<strong>on</strong>fidence<br />

could have serious repercussi<strong>on</strong>s if <strong>firm</strong>s get stuck with adverse l<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

they did not anticipate. The sec<strong>on</strong>d mental short cut is the availability of scenarios (Tversky<br />

& Kahneman, 1974). Managers' experiences dictate how likely they are to perceive that an<br />

event is to occur (Cassidy, 2009, pp. 196-197). For instance, many reinsurance 5 companies<br />

will not insure for a calamity after it has occurred (Greeley, 2011). Even though the<br />

likelihood of another natural disaster is extremely low in an area in which <strong>on</strong>e has already<br />

occurred, managerial percepti<strong>on</strong>s sway reinsurance managers from providing coverage for<br />

such disasters in the future because this is an extreme situati<strong>on</strong> that they fear. This means<br />

that they exclude a lucrative potential market from which they could generate future<br />

4 The terms "people" <strong>and</strong> "managers" are used interchangeably in this Chapter.<br />

5 Reinsurance companies insure insurance companies.<br />

96

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!