20.11.2012 Views

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

How large is liquidity risk <strong>in</strong> an automated auction market? 121<br />

Correspond<strong>in</strong>gly, the Actual VaR at time t−1 for the actual return at time t given<br />

confidence level α is then given by:<br />

where<br />

VaRmb;t ¼ mb;t þ t ; 1 tðrmb;tÞ; (7)<br />

mb;t ¼ t þ 0 þ Xr<br />

i¼1<br />

iðrmb;t 1 t 1ÞÞ<br />

and t ; is the α-percent quantile <strong>of</strong> the student distribution with ν 1<br />

1 degrees <strong>of</strong><br />

freedom. 16 We refer to μmb,t as the mean component and to t ; 1 tðrmb;tÞ as the<br />

volatility component <strong>of</strong> the Actual VaR. With respect to the liquidity risk faced by<br />

an impatient <strong>in</strong>vestor (over the [t−1, t] time <strong>in</strong>terval), VaRmb,t thus provides one<br />

number that both summarizes the expected cost (shaped by the mean component<br />

μmb,t ) and the volatility cost (determ<strong>in</strong>ed by t ; 1 tðrmb;tÞ). This duality is central to<br />

our methodology as it stresses that the liquidity risk for impatient <strong>in</strong>vestors<br />

<strong>in</strong>volves both an expected immediacy cost (which is strongly determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the<br />

volume dependent spread) and a second cost that is related to the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>of</strong> the<br />

trade price for the given traded volume over the [t−1, t] time <strong>in</strong>terval.<br />

In a second step, the computation <strong>of</strong> the relative (i.e. for an actual trade <strong>of</strong> v<br />

shares vs a no trade situation) liquidity risk premium measures which will be<br />

discussed below also requires a VaR estimate based on mid-quote returns (referred<br />

to as frictionless VaR). The econometric specification corresponds to the Actual<br />

VaR with the exception that there is no need to account for a diurnal variation <strong>in</strong><br />

mean returns. 17 For notational convenience let us use the same greeks as for the<br />

actual return specification:<br />

rmm;t ¼ mm;t þ ut;<br />

mm;t ¼ 0 þ Xr<br />

ht ¼ ! þ Xq<br />

irmm;t 1;<br />

i¼1<br />

ut ¼ ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi p<br />

i¼1<br />

ðÞht"t; t<br />

iu 2 Xp<br />

t 1 þ<br />

i¼1<br />

iht 1:<br />

The <strong>in</strong>novations " t are assumed to be <strong>in</strong>dependently identically Student distributed<br />

with ν 2 degrees <strong>of</strong> freedom. t accounts for diurnal variation <strong>in</strong> frictionless<br />

return volatility. Parameter estimation is performed along the same l<strong>in</strong>es as outl<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

above. The frictionless VaR at α percent confidence level is:<br />

VaRmm;t ¼ mm;t þ t ; 2 tðrmm;tÞ: (9)<br />

16 For notational simplicity we suppress the dependence <strong>of</strong> the VaR measures on α as we do not<br />

vary the significance level <strong>in</strong> the empirical analysis.<br />

17 In a weakly efficient market, frictionless returns are serially uncorrelated. However, for ultra<strong>high</strong><br />

<strong>frequency</strong> time horizons, some small statistically significant autocorrelations can be<br />

expected (see Campbell et al. 1997, or Engle 2000).<br />

(8)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!