20.11.2012 Views

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Macroeconomic surprises and short-term behaviour <strong>in</strong> bond futures 271<br />

They assume that this variable captures the <strong>in</strong>tradaily seasonality and the news<br />

effect that standard GARCH models are not able to capture. F<strong>in</strong>ally, two papers focus<br />

on the mean <strong>of</strong> the returns <strong>of</strong> the Treasury bond future and several exchange rates.<br />

Andersen et al. (2003) analyse, <strong>in</strong> a seven year period, the forecast<strong>in</strong>g errors <strong>of</strong> 40<br />

fundamentals us<strong>in</strong>g a very similar approach to Andersen and Bollerslev (1998)<br />

but for the mean. Hautsch and Hess (2002) use the revision unemployment re-<br />

port numbers that <strong>in</strong>clude important variables such as the unemployment rate<br />

and non-farms payrolls.<br />

In this paper 1) the f<strong>in</strong>ancial asset on which we base our analysis is the US<br />

Treasury 10-year bond future, 2) we consider 15 fundamentals represent<strong>in</strong>g different<br />

sectors <strong>of</strong> the economy (<strong>in</strong>flation, real economy, supply and demand confidence<br />

<strong>in</strong>dexes and export–import measures), 3) we are <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

news announcements on the mean rather than on volatility, 4) we consider the<br />

forecast<strong>in</strong>g errors rather than the released numbers, 5) we differentiate between<br />

positive and negative forecast<strong>in</strong>g errors, 6) we assume that the effect <strong>of</strong> the<br />

fundamentals on the bond market differs depend<strong>in</strong>g on the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle (top,<br />

bottom, expansion and contraction), and 7) we use an econometric model that<br />

estimates contemporaneous and ex-post effects <strong>of</strong> the macroeconomic news<br />

smoothly, that is, the parameters that measure the news effect vary smoothly<br />

through time.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> features <strong>of</strong> the paper is the <strong>in</strong>teraction between 5 and 6. That is,<br />

we not only permit good and bad news to affect differently the bond future, but we also<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestigate whether these effects are robust with<strong>in</strong> the economic cycle. If there are<br />

variations, we may conclude that market’s behaviour depends on the mood <strong>of</strong> the<br />

economy or how the market perceives the state <strong>of</strong> the economy. This is related to<br />

the work <strong>in</strong> behavioural economics and, <strong>in</strong> particular, behavioural f<strong>in</strong>ance. S<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

the <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> prospect theory (Kanehman and Tversky 1979), it is well known<br />

that <strong>in</strong>dividuals suffer from an asymmetry between the way they make decisions<br />

<strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g ga<strong>in</strong>s (good news) and decisions <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g losses (bad news). This leads<br />

to a failure <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>variance, i.e. <strong>in</strong>consistent choices (or reactions to good and bad<br />

news) when the same problem (a good or a bad news item) appears <strong>in</strong> different<br />

frames (top, bottom, expansion and contraction <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle). An alternative<br />

means <strong>of</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g why the market responds differently to good and bad<br />

news <strong>in</strong> different phases <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle is by means <strong>of</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty (Veronesi<br />

1999): The market is uncerta<strong>in</strong> about the state <strong>of</strong> the economy. For example, after a<br />

period <strong>of</strong> economic boom, good news will have no effect as traders are already<br />

aware <strong>of</strong> the strength <strong>of</strong> the economy. If, by contrast, bad news start to arrive, the<br />

market reacts because it is not no longer confident about the phase <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

cycle. This <strong>in</strong>troduces more uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and causes an asymmetry <strong>in</strong> the response<br />

to good and bad news. On this basis, Conrad et al. (2002) test this asymmetric<br />

reaction to the news sign and the state <strong>of</strong> the stock market (the equivalent to the<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle <strong>in</strong> our paper). In a firm-specific study, and us<strong>in</strong>g earn<strong>in</strong>gs announcements,<br />

they conclude that price responses to negative earn<strong>in</strong>gs surprises<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease as the difference between the market value at the moment <strong>of</strong> the announcement<br />

and the average market value dur<strong>in</strong>g the last 12 months, <strong>in</strong>creases. In<br />

other words, the effect <strong>of</strong> a negative earn<strong>in</strong>gs surprise is <strong>high</strong>er if the market feels<br />

itself to be <strong>in</strong> expansion with respect to the previous 12 months, than <strong>in</strong> contraction.<br />

Or, put differently, markets respond more strongly to bad news <strong>in</strong> good times. By

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!