20.11.2012 Views

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Asymmetries <strong>in</strong> bid and ask responses to <strong>in</strong>novations <strong>in</strong> the trad<strong>in</strong>g process 57<br />

The terns f i B (MCt, D t) and f i S (MCt, D t), i2{a,b}, are functional forms <strong>of</strong> two<br />

vectors <strong>of</strong> variables. The first vector (MC t) <strong>in</strong>cludes exogenous variables that<br />

characterize the trade and the market environment. The second vector (D t) control<br />

for trad<strong>in</strong>g-time regularities. The particular functional form considered is given <strong>in</strong><br />

Eq. (3.6). We impose l<strong>in</strong>earity for simplicity reasons. The price impact <strong>of</strong> a given<br />

trade is conditioned on these set <strong>of</strong> exogenous and determ<strong>in</strong>istic variables, that we<br />

will specify latter on.<br />

f j<br />

i MCt; ð DtÞ<br />

¼ 1 þ Xn<br />

k¼1<br />

i;j<br />

k MCk t<br />

þ Xn0<br />

h¼1<br />

i; j<br />

h Dh t<br />

; i 2 fa; bg;<br />

j 2 fB; Sg<br />

(3.6)<br />

From Eqs. (3.1) to (3.3), a t and b t are nonstationary, <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>of</strong> order one,<br />

processes. Nonstationarity comes from the common long-run component (m t),<br />

imply<strong>in</strong>g that the time series a t and b t must be co-<strong>in</strong>tegrated. 9 Our application has<br />

the unusual advantage that the co-<strong>in</strong>tegration relationship has a known co<strong>in</strong>tegration<br />

vector (1,−1). The co-<strong>in</strong>tegration relationship is, therefore, a t−b t, the<br />

bid–ask spread (henceforth, s t).<br />

An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> s t represents a departure from the long-run equilibrium<br />

relationship between a t and b t. The error correction mechanism produces simultaneous<br />

revisions <strong>in</strong> both ask and bid quotes that correct such deviations. For this<br />

reason, we <strong>in</strong>corporate s t <strong>in</strong>to Eqs. (3.2)–(3.3) as a determ<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>of</strong> the transitory<br />

components <strong>of</strong> a t and b t. The coefficients α a EC and αb EC show how quickly do at and<br />

b t revert to their common long-run equilibrium value.<br />

3.2 The empirical model<br />

The most common efficient parameterization <strong>of</strong> a vector autoregressive (VAR)<br />

model with co-<strong>in</strong>tegrated variables is, from Granger’s representation theorem <strong>in</strong><br />

Engle and Granger (1987), a vector error correction (VEC) model. In the Appendix I,<br />

we give an explicit derivation <strong>of</strong> the VEC model <strong>in</strong> Eq. (3.7) from the structural<br />

model <strong>in</strong> the previous subsection,<br />

0<br />

10<br />

1<br />

1 0 AaB;t * AaB;t * at<br />

B 0 1 AbB;t * AbS;t * CB<br />

bt C<br />

B<br />

@<br />

0 0 1 0<br />

0 0 0 1<br />

CB<br />

A@<br />

¼<br />

0<br />

B<br />

@<br />

x B t<br />

x S t<br />

C<br />

A<br />

1<br />

ðLÞ ðLÞ C<br />

ð Þ A<br />

ð Þ<br />

st<br />

0<br />

B<br />

1 þ AtðLÞB @<br />

EC<br />

a<br />

EC<br />

b<br />

B L<br />

S L<br />

at 1<br />

bt 1<br />

x B t 1<br />

x S t 1<br />

1<br />

0<br />

ua t<br />

ub t<br />

C<br />

A þ<br />

uB t<br />

uS B<br />

@<br />

t<br />

1<br />

C<br />

A ; (3.7)<br />

9 Engle and Granger (1987), Stock and Watson (1988), Johansen (1991), and Escribano and Peña<br />

(1994), among others, provide formal derivations <strong>of</strong> this result.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!