20.11.2012 Views

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

272<br />

contrast, price responses to positive earn<strong>in</strong>gs surprises do not necessarily <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

<strong>in</strong> bad times with respect to good times.<br />

In this paper we f<strong>in</strong>d similar results to the above studies and more, as our set <strong>of</strong><br />

news is much richer. The basic conclusions we reach are: First, the signs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

responses are all <strong>in</strong>tuitive and the fundamentals that cause most the bond future<br />

changes are (see Table 1 for the acronyms) CC, ISM, UNEM, NFP, PPI, CPI, RS<br />

and IP. On the other hand, HS, GDP, PI, BI and TB have little or no statistical<br />

significance on the bond future. Second, the responses to positive and negative<br />

forecast errors are statistically different. This is the case, for <strong>in</strong>stance, for UNEM,<br />

NFP, CPI and RS. Third, and more importantly, we observe an asymmetry <strong>in</strong><br />

responses to positive and negative forecast<strong>in</strong>g errors at different phases <strong>of</strong> the<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle. In fact, our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs agree with Conrad et al. (2002). Bad news has<br />

the strongest effect when the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle is at the top and <strong>in</strong> contraction. This<br />

suggests that when the economy is at the top <strong>of</strong> the cycle, traders know that sooner<br />

or later the downward part <strong>of</strong> the cycle will start, and hence bad news may be a<br />

signal <strong>of</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the contraction. For equivalent (but <strong>in</strong>verse) reasons, the<br />

smallest effect <strong>of</strong> bad news is when the economy is <strong>in</strong> expansion. Overconfidence<br />

<strong>in</strong> the state <strong>of</strong> the economy may be an explanation. Our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs regard<strong>in</strong>g positive<br />

news also agree with Conrad et al. (2002): They are ambiguous. When the economy<br />

is expand<strong>in</strong>g good news has barely any effect. This is aga<strong>in</strong> a sign that the<br />

market is overconfident. However, when the economy is contract<strong>in</strong>g, positive and<br />

negative news have similar effect. This suggests that, regardless <strong>of</strong> the sign <strong>of</strong> the<br />

error, news <strong>in</strong>creases uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. Fourth, timel<strong>in</strong>ess matter, i.e. the sooner the<br />

fundamental is released, the more it <strong>in</strong>fluences the bond future. This is strongly<br />

related to the first conclusion. For example, CC is the first number released, at the<br />

end <strong>of</strong> the month it is report<strong>in</strong>g on, and it has an important <strong>in</strong>fluence. On the<br />

contrary, BI is released two months after the month it is cover<strong>in</strong>g and has barely<br />

any <strong>in</strong>fluence. These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs are also found by Flemm<strong>in</strong>g and Remolona (1999)<br />

and Hess (2004).<br />

The rest <strong>of</strong> the paper is organized as follows; Section 2 shows the f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

model, Section 3 expla<strong>in</strong>s the econometric methodology, Section 4 discusses the<br />

data, Section 5 shows and discusses the results and Section 6 draws conclusions.<br />

2 On the components <strong>of</strong> short run price movements<br />

D. Veredas<br />

The hypothesis underly<strong>in</strong>g this paper is that temporary jumps observed <strong>in</strong> the<br />

pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial assets reflect: 1) the market expectation <strong>of</strong> fundamental factors<br />

driv<strong>in</strong>g the asset valuation (e.g. <strong>in</strong>flation or unemployment) and 2) the time <strong>in</strong> the<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle where these expectations are formed (and potential signs <strong>of</strong> reversal<br />

<strong>of</strong> the cycle) i.e. the idea <strong>of</strong> look<strong>in</strong>g past the immediate macroeconomic release.<br />

To measure the effect on market expectation <strong>of</strong> fundamentals driv<strong>in</strong>g asset<br />

valuation, we need an asset and a set <strong>of</strong> fundamentals. Among all the f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

markets, we chose the bond market. Bonds are the most widely used <strong>of</strong> all the<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>struments. In particular, we chose the 10 year Treasury Note 6% day<br />

session Future (TY) because it is a liquid and important contract and reflects the<br />

general response <strong>of</strong> the yield curve to news. The ten year future is a reflection <strong>of</strong><br />

the state <strong>of</strong> the US bond market with maturities between seven and ten years. It is<br />

an efficient way <strong>of</strong> construct<strong>in</strong>g a long time series that is not subject to the prob-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!