20.11.2012 Views

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

recent developments in high frequency financial ... - Index of

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Macroeconomic surprises and short-term behaviour <strong>in</strong> bond futures 273<br />

lems encountered by tak<strong>in</strong>g a particular bond (for <strong>in</strong>stance, when a bond matures its<br />

price represents shorter and shorter yields). Regard<strong>in</strong>g the fundamentals, we chose<br />

15 different numbers, represent<strong>in</strong>g wide areas <strong>of</strong> the economy such as real economy,<br />

<strong>in</strong>flation, confidence <strong>in</strong>dexes and export-import measures (we refer to Table 1<br />

and Section 4 for further details).<br />

The second component that affects short run jumps <strong>in</strong> asset prices is the<br />

momentum <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle. Follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>recent</strong> literature on behavioural f<strong>in</strong>ance<br />

and Veronesi (1999), we conjecture that the effect <strong>of</strong> the fundamentals on TY<br />

depends on the general economic situation <strong>of</strong> the economy. For example, it is<br />

<strong>in</strong>tuitive to believe that the effect <strong>of</strong> a positive surprise <strong>in</strong> the unemployment rate<br />

on the TY is not the same when the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle is <strong>in</strong> contraction as when it is<br />

<strong>in</strong> expansion. As measure <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle we use the Institute for Supply<br />

Management Survey (ISM) <strong>in</strong>dex. The difference between ISM and other<br />

measures <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle, such as GDP, is that it is the most forwardlook<strong>in</strong>g<br />

measure available <strong>of</strong> the market s<strong>in</strong>ce it is based on expectations. The<br />

ISM <strong>in</strong>dex is the result <strong>of</strong> a survey among 300 people selected from 20 manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries. The survey <strong>in</strong>cludes questions related to new orders, production,<br />

employment, supplier deliveries and <strong>in</strong>ventories (see Niemira and Zukowsky<br />

(1998, chapter 19) for further details). In order to see the effect <strong>of</strong> the fundamentals<br />

on the TY, we divide the ISM accord<strong>in</strong>g to two criteria: 1) if it is expand<strong>in</strong>g or<br />

contract<strong>in</strong>g and 2) if it is above, below or <strong>in</strong> between (differentiat<strong>in</strong>g as well<br />

expansions and contractions) upper and a lower thresholds (further details are<br />

given <strong>in</strong> Section 4).<br />

Ideally, we would like to estimate a model like<br />

ð1LÞTYt ¼ ½ 1: þ 2ðtrend strength <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycletÞ<br />

þ ðtrend strength <strong>of</strong> TY ÞðN Š E½N ŠÞ þ ";<br />

3 t t t t (1)<br />

where Nt is the fundamental, E [N t] its expectation, and hence Nt EN ½ tŠ<br />

is the<br />

forecast<strong>in</strong>g error (or surprise or news).<br />

The effect <strong>of</strong> the news <strong>in</strong> TY is caused by the news itself as well as by the trend<br />

strength <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle and the trend strength <strong>of</strong> the future bond. At each<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time, the market has a work<strong>in</strong>g hypothesis as to where the economy is and<br />

where it is go<strong>in</strong>g. Simplistically, the macroeconomic releases are test<strong>in</strong>g the market<br />

hypothesis. No drastic price response should be seen if the number falls <strong>in</strong> a<br />

reasonable range around the expectations. If the macroeconomic releases fall<br />

beyond the reasonable bounds, measured by the forecast<strong>in</strong>g error, the re-pric<strong>in</strong>g<br />

effect should be proportional to the forecast error (coefficient α1).<br />

In reality, more factors are at work and they should be evident mostly around<br />

the changes <strong>in</strong> macroeconomic trends. In general, agents are not very good at<br />

call<strong>in</strong>g market tops or bottoms and when the economy is perceived to be turn<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

one usually sees a rush to close or reverse exist<strong>in</strong>g positions. Agents are unsure <strong>of</strong><br />

whether a turn is occurr<strong>in</strong>g or whether the number is a statistical fluke <strong>in</strong> the<br />

macroeconomic trend. So we expect an asymmetry <strong>in</strong> the market’s response to<br />

positive or negative forecast errors at perceived phases <strong>of</strong> the economic cycle. This<br />

is represented by coefficient α2.<br />

This asymmetry can be exacerbated by the net position<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the speculator and<br />

hedgers community. The speculators community are usually trend followers and

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!