23.01.2014 Views

Hedging Strategy and Electricity Contract Engineering - IFOR

Hedging Strategy and Electricity Contract Engineering - IFOR

Hedging Strategy and Electricity Contract Engineering - IFOR

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

4.5 Nuclear plant 91<br />

of 1000 MW. Over 16% of the world’s electricity is generated from nuclear<br />

plants [HL00].<br />

The nuclear plant has very low marginal costs, which typically amounts<br />

to a third of the marginal costs in a coal plant <strong>and</strong> between a fourth <strong>and</strong> a<br />

fifth of those for a gas combined-cycle plant [OEC98]. 14 The flexibility is<br />

unfortunately very low, caused by the high costs associated with varying the<br />

output. There have actually been occasions in, for example, France when EdF<br />

has been willing to sell nuclear produced electricity at negative prices due to<br />

these high costs. Nuclear plants are because of the low marginal costs <strong>and</strong> low<br />

flexibility used for base load. Not only are nuclear plants subject to the start-up<br />

times <strong>and</strong> shut-down losses that coal <strong>and</strong> oil plants suffer from, they are also<br />

subject to a much more complex heating procedure. Whereas a coal plant or<br />

an oil plant fairly easy can change output by simply regulating the amount of<br />

fuel <strong>and</strong> air, the fission reaction is more sensitive to quick ramp ups <strong>and</strong> ramp<br />

downs.<br />

The low operational flexibility, forcing the plant to run over long periods of<br />

time, implies that the owner has to take a decision whether to produce or not<br />

in the future where the spot prices are uncertain. However, a series of long<br />

future contracts would perfectly replicate this stable amount of produced electricity,<br />

which consequently are the nuclear plant’s corresponding contracts. But<br />

even if the flexibility would be high <strong>and</strong> the output could be changed instantly,<br />

the option value would be small. Assuming a high operational flexibility, the<br />

owner would in each period have the possibility to decide whether to produce<br />

or not <strong>and</strong> the plant would hence equal a series of hourly options. Since the<br />

marginal cost <strong>and</strong> hence the corresponding option’s strike price is so low, the<br />

decision would however essentially solely be to produce. The options would<br />

normally be deep in-the-money, 15 since the spot price by far would exceed the<br />

low marginal cost. A possibility to not produce would consequently have a low<br />

value. Generally, the more an option is in-the-money, the more the asymmetric<br />

payoff is lost <strong>and</strong> therefore more of the option features are lost, 16 which is il-<br />

14 Marginal cost is here defined as the total fuel cost, including waste management.<br />

15 A call option is out-of-the-money if the underlying price S is lower than strike price K<br />

<strong>and</strong> vice versa for a put option. An option is at-the-money if ­ S K . A call option is<br />

in-the-money if ® S K <strong>and</strong> vice versa for a put option.<br />

16 One important option feature is the possibility to achieve high returns with only mod-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!