04.02.2015 Views

Life – a user's manual Part II - Boksidan

Life – a user's manual Part II - Boksidan

Life – a user's manual Part II - Boksidan

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

State revenues<br />

In the Middle Ages, the State (i.e. the king), mainly had the following types of income:<br />

Goods produced in his own farms 9 .<br />

Taxes 10 .<br />

Selling currency 11 .<br />

Duties (see the chapter about customs).<br />

Sale of goods that come in the form of tax.<br />

Sales of goods produced in his farms.<br />

Sale of state farms.<br />

Taking back land previously given away.<br />

Leasing the right to tax the people in a certain area 12 .<br />

9.<br />

During the early Middle Ages the king's main source of income was the land he owned (royal estates). In 1560, for<br />

example, 28.5% of Sweden's agricultural land was owned by the King (Eli F. Heckscher, Svensk ekonomisk<br />

historia, Bonnier, Stockholm, 1935). The nobles held 21.4% and ordinary peasants owned the remaining 50.1%.<br />

For logistical reasons the king distributed his people over the different estates so that they, on the spot, could<br />

consume his income.<br />

10.<br />

11.<br />

12.<br />

Originally, the king's land were about his only income. Taxes were not. However, everybody had the duty to<br />

defend the country and provide som services to the king. Such service was the obligation to host the king and his<br />

entourage when they were traveling.<br />

During the 1200s the country's army transformed from only consisting un-professionals doing their duty to also<br />

consist of professional fighters, who were rewarded (see defense) and fortifications (castles) were also required. It<br />

costed the king a lot of money and the problem was solved by the former defense duty was converted to the<br />

requirement to pay taxes (apart from those who were exempt because they could set up armored warriors on<br />

horseback, I.e. Nobility).<br />

The tax was different depending on whether the taxpayer was a farmer or living in a town. Unfairly enough, town<br />

taxes were low, for example, the tax for a small town like Östhammar did not exceeded what four peasant<br />

homesteads paid. And some cities, such as Stockholm and Kalmar was periodically even exempt.<br />

According to the accounts the king recieved in 1573 in 276 655.5 daler in taxes. 354.5 of these flowed into the form<br />

of cash while the rest came in the form of, among other things: butter, 32 412 daler, wooden planks 1 217.625<br />

daler, days worked (i.e. work for the state) 17 715.5 daler, leather goods 1 846 daler, and copper 15 828.250 daler.<br />

The largest of all forms of payment were rye and barley (26.6% of all taxes), followed by butter (11.7%) and horses<br />

(11.0%).<br />

The king had a monopoly on producing coins. Normally the coins were stamped with as high as the value of the<br />

silver they contained, but sometimes the king lowered the silver content without changing the coins stamped<br />

values.<br />

The king could lease out right to collect taxes to someone else. In 1530/31, for example, others had the right to<br />

collect taxes (Eli F. Heckscher, Svensk ekonomisk historia,, Bonnier, Stockholm, 1935) in the cities, Nykoping,<br />

Örebro, Västervik, Ulvila and Viborg, and districts, Öland, South/East/West Vedbo, Konga, Kinnevalds, Sevede,<br />

Anbyrde and Möre, as well as large parts of Finland since the counties Viborg, Savonlinna and Porvoo were leased<br />

out.<br />

91

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!