24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

236 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

:h, ... "jr",~ 7 The Cost of Production 237<br />

firm looking only at the high initial labor requirement -will obtain an m"erly pessimistic<br />

vie-w of the business. Suppose the firm plans to be in bus~ness for "a long<br />

time, producing 10 units per year. Suppose the total labor reqUlrement tor the<br />

first year's production is 10. In the first year of production, the firm's cost v"ill be<br />

high as it learns the business. But once the learning effect has taken place, production<br />

costs will falL After 8 years, the labor required to produce 10 units will<br />

be only 5.1, and per-unit cost will be roughly half what it was in the first year of<br />

production_ Thus the learning curve can be important for a firm deciding<br />

whether it is profitable to enter an industry.<br />

100<br />

Production<br />

Hours<br />

per Aircraft 80<br />

60<br />

JO<br />

Awrage for First 100 Aircraft<br />

20<br />

Suppose that as the manager of a firm that has just entered the chemical processing<br />

indush,)" you face the following problem: Should you produce a relatively<br />

Im'\' level of output and sell at a high price, or should you price your<br />

product lower and increase your rate of sales The second alternative is appealing<br />

if there is a learning CUIye in this industry In that case, the increased volume<br />

will lower your average production costs over time and increase the firm's<br />

profitability.<br />

To decide what to do, you can examine the available statistical evidence that<br />

distinguishes the components of the learning curve (learning new processes by<br />

labor, engineering improvements, etc.) from increasing returns to scale. For<br />

example, a study of 37 chemical products reveals that cost reductions in the<br />

chemical processing industry are directly tied to the growth of cumulative<br />

indush'Y output, to inveshnent in improved capital equipment, and, to a lesser<br />

extent, to economies of scale ll In fact, for the entire sample of chemical products,<br />

average costs of production fall at 5.5 percent per yeaL The Shldy reveals<br />

that for each doubling of plant scale, the average cost of production falls by<br />

11 percent For each doubling of cumulative output, however, the average cost<br />

of production falls by 27 percent The evidence shows clearly that learning<br />

effects are more important than economies of scale in the chemical processing<br />

industryY<br />

The learning curve has also been shown to be important in the semiconductor<br />

indushy A study of seven generations of dynamic random-access memory<br />

(DRAM) semiconductors from 1974 to 1992 fOlmd that the learning rates averaged<br />

about 20 percent; thus a 10-percent increase in cumulative production<br />

OL-______ L-____ ~ ______ -L ______ ~ ____ ~ __ _<br />

o 100 200 300 400 500<br />

Number of Aircraft Produced<br />

The learning curve relates the labor requirement per aircraft to the cumulative number<br />

of aircraft produced. As the production process becomes better organized and<br />

workers familiarity with their jobs, labor requirements fall dramatically<br />

would lead to a 2-percent decrease in cost,u The study also compared learning<br />

bv firms in Japan to firms in the United States and found that there was no dis­<br />

~guishable difference in the speed of learning.<br />

Another example is the aircraft industry, where studies have fOlmd learning<br />

rates that are as high as 40 percent This is illustrated in Figure 7_14, which<br />

shows the labor requirements for production of aircraft by Airbus Industrie.<br />

Obsen"e that the first 10 or 20 airplanes require far more labor to produce than<br />

the hundredth or two hundredth airplane. Also note how the learning cun'e<br />

flattens out after a certain point; in this case, nearly all learning is complete<br />

after 200 airplanes have been built.<br />

Learning curve effects can be important in determining the shape of longrun<br />

cost curves and can thus help guide managem_ent decisions. Managers can<br />

use learning CUITe information to decide whether a production operation is<br />

profitable and, if it is, how to plan how large the plant operation and the volume<br />

of cumulative output need be to generate a positive cash flow.<br />

11 The studv was conducted by MaITin Lieberman, "The Learning Cun"e and Pricing in the Chemical<br />

Processing"Industries," RAND JOllmal of Economics 15 (198J): 213-28_<br />

12 The author used the average cost AC of the chemical products, the cumulati\:e industry<br />

output X, and the a\-erage scale of a production plant Z. He then estimated the relatlOnshlp log<br />

(AC) - 0387 log (X) - OJ73 log (Z). The - 0387 coefficient on cumulative output tells us that f~~<br />

e\"ery I-percent increase in cumulative output, average cost decreases 0387 percent. The - 0.1/~<br />

coefficient on plant size tells us that for e\-ery I-percent increase in plant size, cost decreases 0.17J<br />

percent<br />

By interpreting the two coefficients in lio-ht of the output and plant-size variables, we can allocate<br />

about 15 percent of the cost reduction to i~creases in the average scale of plants and 85 percent to<br />

increases in cumulative industry output. Suppose plant scale doubled while cumulati\-e output<br />

increased by a factor of 5 during the study. In that case, costs would fall by 11 percent from the<br />

increased scale and by 62 percent from the increase in cumulati\"e output<br />

A business that is expanding or contracting its operation must predict how costs<br />

will change as output changes. Estimates of future costs can be obtained from a<br />

cost function, which relates the cost of production to the level of output and<br />

other variables that the firm can control.<br />

13The study \,-as conducted by D A. Irwin and P J Kleno,,", "Learning-by-Doing Spillo\-ers in the<br />

Semiconductor Industry," Journal of Political Eco1l01I1I/102 (December 199J): 1200-27<br />

cost function Function relating<br />

cost of production to le\'el<br />

of output and other variables<br />

that the firm can controL

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!