24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

270 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

8 Profit Maximization and Competitive Supply<br />

(dollars per<br />

unit of<br />

output)<br />

Producer<br />

Surplus<br />

A - ___( _________ J}<br />

MC<br />

P<br />

Price<br />

(dollars per<br />

. unit of<br />

output)<br />

P'<br />

o<br />

'1*<br />

Output<br />

o<br />

Q* Output<br />

The producer surplus for a fum is measured by the yellow area below the<br />

price and above the marginal cost curve, between outputs 0 and q*, the profitmaximizing<br />

output. Alternatively, it is equal to rectangle ABeD because the sum<br />

all marginal costs up to q* is equal to the variable costs of producing q*.<br />

When we add the marginal costs of producing each level of output from 0 to<br />

q*, we find that the sum is the total variable cost of producing q*. Marginal cost<br />

reflects increments to cost associated ''''ith increases in output; because fixed cost<br />

does not vary with output, the sum of all marginal costs must equal the sum of<br />

the firm's variable costS.6 Thus producer surplus can alternatively be defined as<br />

the difference between the firm's reven1le and its total variable cost. In Figure 8.11, producer<br />

surplus is also given by the rectangle ABCD, which equals revenue<br />

(OABq*) minus variable cost (ODCq*).<br />

versus Producer surplus is closely related to<br />

profit but is not equal to it. In the short run, producer surplus is equal to reven~e<br />

minus variable cost, which is variable profit. Total profit, on the other hand, IS<br />

equal to revenue minus all costs, both variable and fixed:<br />

Producer surplus PS = R<br />

Profit = 7i = R<br />

VC<br />

VC - FC<br />

It follows that in the short run, when fixed cost is positive, producer surplus is<br />

greater than profit.<br />

The extent to which firms enjoy producer surplus depends on their cos~s of<br />

production. Higher-cost firms have less producer surplus, and IO'wer-cost fn:ns<br />

have more. By adding up the producer surpluses of all firms, we can determm e<br />

the producer surplus for a market. This can be seen in Figure 8.12. The market<br />

6 The area under the marginal cost curve from 0 to '1* is TC(q*) TC(O) = IC - FC = VC<br />

The producer surplus for a market is the area below the market price and above the<br />

market supply curve, between 0 and output Q*.<br />

supply curve begins at the vertical axis at a point representing the average variable<br />

cost of the lowest-cost finn in the market. Producer surplus is the area that<br />

lies below the market price of the product and above the supply curve between<br />

the output levels 0 and Q*.<br />

8.7<br />

In the long run, a firm can alter all its inputs, including plant size. It can decide<br />

to shut down (i.e, to exit the industry) or to begin producing a product for the<br />

first time (Le., to enter an industry). Because vve are concerned here 'with competitiw<br />

markets, 'we allow for free entnj and free exit. In other words, we are assuming<br />

that finns may enter or" exit Without ~ny legal restriction or any special costs<br />

associated with entry. (Recall from Section 8.1 that this is one of the key assumptions<br />

underlying perfect competition.) After analyzing the long-run output decision<br />

of a profit-maximizing firm in a competitive market, we discuss the nature<br />

of competitive equilibrium in the long run. We also discuss the relationship<br />

behveen entry and economic and accounting profits.<br />

long=Run<br />

Maximization<br />

Figure 8.13 shows how a competitive firm makes its long-run, profit-maximizing<br />

output decision. As in the short run, it faces a horizontal demand curve. (In<br />

Figure 8.13 the finn takes the market price of 540 as given.) Its short-nUl average<br />

(total) cost curve SAC and short-run marginal cost curve SMC are low enough<br />

for the firm to make a positive profit, given by rectangle ABCD, by producing an<br />

output of q1, where SMC = P = MR. The long-run average cost curve LAC

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!