24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

84 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

corner solution Situation in<br />

which the marginal rate of<br />

substitution for one good in a<br />

chosen market basket is not<br />

equal to the slope of the budget<br />

line.<br />

outward from PQ to TV in Figure 3.1-l:(a), where PT = QV is the dollar<br />

amount of the grant The local gm'ernment's response to this int1ux of dollars<br />

is to move to a higher indifference cun'e by selecting market basket B, with<br />

more of both goods (OU of pri\'ate expenditures and OZ of police expend i­<br />

hues). But more pri\'ate expenditures means that some of the money for<br />

police that came pre\'iously from taxes now comes from government grants.<br />

The second type of program is the lIlotelzillg grallt-funds offered as a form of<br />

subsidy to local spending. For example, the federal govemment might offer 51 for<br />

every $2 that the local gm'emment raises to pay for police. As a result, a matching<br />

grant lowers the cost of the publicly provided good. In terms of Figure 3.14(b), the<br />

matching grant rotates the budget line ouhvard from PQ to PR. If no local money<br />

is spent on police, the budget line is unchanged. However, if the local official<br />

decides to spend money on the public sectOl~ the budget increases.<br />

In response to the matching grant, the official chooses market basket C rather<br />

than A As ,·"ith a nonmatching grant, there is an increase in police expenditures<br />

and a tax cut that leads to an increase in pri\'ate consumption. At C OX dollars<br />

are allocated to police and OW to private expenditures. Hovvever, the spending<br />

effects of the hvo types of grant are different The diagram shows that the matching<br />

grant leads to greater police spending than does the nonmatching grant,<br />

even vvhen the two programs involve identical govemment expenditures. s<br />

- '"<br />

Corner Solutions<br />

Sometimes consumers buy in extremes, at least within categories of goods. Some<br />

people, for example, spend no money on travel and entertainment. Indifference<br />

curve analysis can be used to show conditions under which consumers choose<br />

not to consume a particular good.<br />

In Figure 3.15, a man faced with budget line for snacks AB chooses to purchase<br />

only ice cream (IC) and no frozen yogurt (Y). This decision ret1ects what is<br />

called a comer solution: \~hen one of the goods is not consumed, the consumption<br />

bundle appears at the corner of the graph. At B, which is the point of maximum<br />

satisfaction, the MRS of ice cream for frozen yogurt is greater than the<br />

slope of the budget line. This inequality suggests that if the consumer had more<br />

frozen yogurt to give up, he would gladly trade it for additional ice cream. At<br />

this point, howe\'er, our consumer is already consuming all ice cream and no<br />

frozen yogurt, and it is impossible to consume negative amounts of frozen<br />

yogurt.<br />

When I] corner solutioll arises, the consulller's MRS does not necessarily eqlli1! the<br />

price mtio. Unlike the condition expressed in equation (3,3), the necessary condition<br />

for satisfaction to be maximized when choosing between ice cream and<br />

frozen yogurt in a corner solution is gi\'en by the following inequality:9<br />

-<br />

we",<br />

Frozen Yogurt<br />

(cups per<br />

month)<br />

A<br />

B<br />

ew & &<br />

Ice cream<br />

(cups per month)<br />

IAlhen the conswner's marginal rate of substitution is not equal to the price ratio for<br />

all levels of consumption, a corner solution arises, The conswner maximizes satisfaction<br />

by consuming only one of the two goods. Given budget line AB, the highest<br />

level of satisfaction is achieved at B on indifference curve U j , where the Iv1RS (of ice<br />

cream for frozen yogmt) is greater than the ratio of the price of ice cream to the price<br />

of frozen yogurt.<br />

This inequality would, of course, be reversed if the corner solution were at point<br />

A rather than B. In either case, we can see that the marginal benefit-marginal<br />

cost equality that we described in the previous section holds only when positive<br />

quantities of all goods are consumed,<br />

An important lesson here is that predictions about how much of a product<br />

consumers will purchase when faced 'with changing economic conditions<br />

depend on the nature of consumer preferences for that product and related<br />

products and on the slope of the consumer's budget line. If the MRS of ice cream<br />

for frozen yogurt is substantially greater than the price ratio, as in Figure 3.15,<br />

then a small decrease in the price of frozen yogurt will not alter the consumer's<br />

choice; he will still choose to consume only ice cream. But if the price of frozen<br />

yogurt falls far enough, the consumer could quickly choose to consume a lot of<br />

frozen yogurt.<br />

Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior 85<br />

(3.4)<br />

S Note also that point B, which is attained with a non matching grant, is on a higher indifference<br />

ClaTe than point C. which is attained with a matching grant The nonmatching grant leads to greater<br />

satisfaction for the same le\'el of expenditure. In other \\'ords, there is a trade-off between encouraging<br />

a particular change in expenditure and achie\'ing the highest le\'el of satisfaction for a gi\en<br />

expenditure.<br />

9 Strict equality could hold if the slope of the budget constraint happened to equal the slope of the<br />

indifference cu[\'e-a condition that is unlikely<br />

J<br />

ane Doe's parents have provided a trust hmd for her college education, Jane,<br />

,·"ho is 18, can receive the entire trust fund on the condition that she spend it<br />

only on education. The fund is a welcome gift to Jane but perhaps not as<br />

welcome as an unrestricted trust. To see ,'\'hy Jane feels this way, consider<br />

Figure 3.16, in which dollars per year spent on education are shown on the horizontal<br />

axis and dollars spent on other forms of consumption on the vertical.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!