24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

356 Part 3 Market Structure and Competitive Strategy<br />

Chapter 10 Market Power: Monopoly and Monopsony 357<br />

S/Q<br />

P*<br />

S/Q<br />

ME<br />

marginal value of the product, and thus they \'vill have little monopsony<br />

On the other hand, if those buyers compete less aggressively, or even colprices<br />

will not be bid ~lP ver~ much, and the buyers' degree of monopsony<br />

ower might be nearly as hIgh as If there ,,,'ere only one buyer.<br />

P So as with rnonopoly power, there is no simple way to predict how much<br />

onopsony power buyers will have in a market. We can count the number of<br />

~yers, and we can often estimate the el~sticity ~f supply, but that is n~t enough.<br />

Monopsony power also depends on the mteractlOn among buyers, whIch can be<br />

more difficult to ascertain.<br />

Q*<br />

(a)<br />

MY<br />

Quantity<br />

Q* Quantity<br />

(b)<br />

Monopsony power depends on the elasticity of supply. When sup!ly is elasti~, as in (a), r:1~rginal expenditure<br />

average expenditure do not differ by much, so price is close to what It would be m a competitive market. The<br />

is true when supply is inelastic, as in (b).<br />

Sources of Monopsony Power<br />

\Vhat determines the degree of monopsony power in a market Again, we can<br />

draw analogies with monopoly and monopoly power. We saw that monopoly<br />

pO'wer depends on three things: the elasticity of market demand, the number of<br />

sellers in the market, and how those sellers interact. Monopsony power depends<br />

on three similar things: The elasticity of market supply, the number of buyers in<br />

the market, and how those buyers interact<br />

Elasticity<br />

A monopsonist benefits because it faces an<br />

upward-sloping supply curve, so that marginal expenditure exceeds average<br />

expendihll'e. The less elastic the supply curve, the greater the difference between<br />

marainal expenditure and averaae expendihlre and the more monopsony power<br />

b b . 'ts<br />

the buyer enjoys. If only one buyer is in the market-a pure monopsorust-l<br />

monopsony power is completely determined by the elasticity of market su~plr'<br />

If supply is highly elastic, monopsony power is small and there is little gam m<br />

being the only buyer.<br />

Most markets have more than one buyer, and the number<br />

of buyers is an important determinant of monopsony power. When the n~'<br />

bel' of buyers is very larae no sinale buyer can have much influence over prIce.<br />

Thus each buyer fa~es a~1 'extrem~lv el;stic supply curve, so that the market is<br />

almost compl~tely competitive. The" potential for Inonopsony power arises when<br />

the number of buyers is limited.<br />

Finally, suppose three or four buyers are in the<br />

market. If those buyers compete aggressively, they will bid up the price close to<br />

The Social Costs of Monopsony Power<br />

Because monopsony power results in lower prices and lm'\'er quantities purchased,<br />

,ve would expect it to make the buyer better off and sellers worse off.<br />

But suppose we value the welfare of buyers and sellers equally. How is aggrerrate<br />

welfare affected by monopsony power<br />

l:1 We can find out by comparing the consumer and producer surplus that<br />

results from a competitive market to the surplus that results when a monopsonist<br />

is the sole buyer. Figure 10.17 shows the average and marginal expenditure<br />

curves and marginal value curve for the monopsonist. The monopsonist's net<br />

benefit is maximized by purchasing a quantity Q/1/ at a price P/1/ such that marginal<br />

value equals marginal expendihlre. In a competitive market, price equals<br />

marginal value. Thus the competitive price and quantity, Pc and Qo are found<br />

where the average expenditure and marginal value curves intersect. Now let's<br />

see how surplus changes if we move from the competitive price and quantity, Pc'<br />

and QCI to the monopsony price and quantity, P/1/ and Q,w<br />

S/Q<br />

The shaded rectangle and triangles show changes in consumer and producer surpl~s<br />

when moving from competitive price and quantity, Pc and Qu to monopsonist's<br />

pnce and quantity, P'1l and Q/1/' Because both price and quantity are lower, there is an<br />

Increase in buyer (consumer) surplus given by A-B. Producer surplus falls by<br />

..;! + C, so there is a deadweight loss given by h-iangles Band C.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!