24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

108 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

4 Individual and Market Demand<br />

Figure 4.4(b), derived from Figure 4.3, shows the Engel curve for hamburger.<br />

We see that hamburger consumption increases from 5 to 10 units as income<br />

increases from $10 to $20. As income increases further, from $20 to $30, consumption<br />

falls to 8 units. The portion of the Engel curve that slopes downward<br />

is the income range in which hamburger is an inferior good.<br />

'"'<br />

-¥<br />

.-\nnual 580,000<br />

Income<br />

70,000<br />

60,000<br />

W55iw0§ii§<br />

x<br />

50,000<br />

The Engel curves we just examined apply to individual consumers.<br />

However, we can also derive Engel curves for groups of consumers. This<br />

information is particularly useful if we want to see how consumer spending<br />

varies among different income groups. Table 4.1 illush'ates these spending patterns<br />

for several items taken from a survey by the U.s. Bureau of Labor<br />

Statistics. Although the data are averaged over many households, they can be<br />

interpreted as describing the expenditures of a typical family.<br />

Note that the data relate expenditures on a particular item rather than the<br />

q1lantity of the item to income. The first two items, entertainment and owned<br />

dwellings, are consumption goods for which the income elasticity of demand is<br />

high. Average family expendihlres on entertainment increase almost eightfold<br />

when we move from the lowest to highest income group. The same pattern<br />

applies to the purchase of homes: There is a more than tenfold increase in<br />

expenditures from the lowest to the highest category.<br />

In contrast, expenditures on rental housing actually fall with income. This<br />

pattern reflects the fact that most higher-income individuals own rather than<br />

rent homes. Thus rental housing is an inferior good, at least for incomes above<br />

$30,000 per year. Finally, note that health care, food, and clothing are consumption<br />

items for which the income elasticities are positive, but not as high as for<br />

entertainment or owner-occupied housing.<br />

The data Ul Table 4.1 have been plotted in Figure 4.5 for rented dwellings,<br />

health care, and entertainment. Observe in the three Engel curves that as<br />

.. ±O,OOO<br />

30,000<br />

20,000<br />

10,000<br />

° SO 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500 5,000<br />

Annual Expenditure<br />

Average per-capita expenditures on rented dwellulgs, health care, and entertainment<br />

are plotted as functions of illU1ual income, Health care and entertainment are<br />

superior goods: Expenditures increase with income, Rental housing, however, is an<br />

inferior good for incomes above $30,000.<br />

&%<br />

income rises, expenditures on entertainment increase rapidly while expenditures<br />

on rental housing increase when uKome is low, but decrease once income<br />

exceeds 530,000.<br />

Substitutes and Complements<br />

EXPENDITURES<br />

($) ON:<br />

Entertainment<br />

Owned dwellings<br />

Rented dwellings<br />

Health care<br />

Food<br />

Clothing<br />

INCOME GROUP (1997 $)<br />

LESS THAN 10,000- 20,000- 30,000- 40,000- 50,000- 70,000<br />

10,000 19,000 29,000 39,000 49,000 69,000 AND ABOVE<br />

700 947 1,274 1,514 2,054 2,654 4,300<br />

1,116 1,725 2,253 3,243 4,454 5,793 9,898<br />

1,957 2,170 2,371 2,536 2,137 1,540 1,266<br />

1,031 1,697 1,918 1,820 2,052 2,214 2,642<br />

2,656 3,385 4,109 4,888 5,429 6,220 8,279<br />

859 978 1,363 1,772 1,778 2,614 3,442<br />

Source: u.s. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, "Consumer Expenditure Survey: 1997."<br />

The demand curves that we graphed in Chapter 2 showed the relationship<br />

between the price of a good and the quantity demanded, vvith preferences,<br />

income, and the prices of all other goods held constant. For many goods,<br />

demand is related to the consumption and prices of other goods. Baseball bats<br />

and baseballs, hot dogs and mustard, and computer hardware and software are<br />

all examples of goods that tend to be used together. Other goods, such as cola<br />

and diet cola, owner-occupied houses and rental aparhnents, movie tickets and<br />

videocassette rentals, tend to substitute for one another.<br />

Recall from Section 2.4 that two goods are substitutes if an increase in the price<br />

of one leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of the other. If the price of a<br />

movie ticket rises, \'\'e would expect individuals to rent more videos, because<br />

mo\'ie tickets and videos are substitutes. Similarly, hvo goods are cOlllplelllents if an<br />

increase in the price of one good leads to a decrease in the quantity demanded of<br />

the other. If the price of gasoline goes up, causulg gasoline consumption to fall,<br />

we would expect the consumption of motor oil to fall as well, because gasoline<br />

and motor oil are used together. Two goods are illdepelldellt if a change in the<br />

price of one good has no effect on the quantity demanded of the other.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!