24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

~-<br />

262 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

Chapter 8 Profit Maximization and Competitive Supply 263<br />

First, except under limited circumstances, nL'emge -unrinble cost sizol!ld /lot be<br />

used ns n substitute for mnrgillnl cost. When marginal and ave~age cost are nearly<br />

constant, there is little difference between them. Hmyever, it both marginal and<br />

average cost are increasing sharply, the use of average variable cost can be mis.<br />

leading in deciding hm\' much to produce. Suppose for example, that a com.<br />

pany has the foUovA/ing cost information:<br />

Current output<br />

Materials cost<br />

Labor cost<br />

100 units per day, 80 of v-vhich are produced<br />

during the regular shift and 20 of which are<br />

produced during overtime<br />

$8 per unit for all output<br />

$30 per unit for the regular shift; 550 per unit<br />

for the overtime shift<br />

Let's calculate average variable cost and marginal cost for the first 80 units of<br />

output and then see how both cost measures change when we include the<br />

additional 20 lmits produced with overtime labor. For the first 80 units, average<br />

variable cost is simply the labor cost ($2400 $30 per unit X 80 units)<br />

plus the materials cost ($640 = $8 per unit X 80 units) divided by the 80<br />

units-($2400 + $640)/80 = $38 per unit. Because the average variable cost is<br />

the same for each unit of output, the marginal cost is also equal to 538 per<br />

unit.<br />

When output increases to 100 units per day, both average variable cost and<br />

marginal cost change. The variable cost has now increased; it includes the additional<br />

materials cost of $160 (20 units X $8 per urut) and the additional labor<br />

cost of $1000 (20 units X $50 per unit). Average variable cost is therefore the<br />

total labor cost plus the materials cost ($2400 + $1000 + $640 + $160) divided<br />

by the 100 lmitS of output, or $42 per urut.<br />

What about marginal cost While the materials cost per unit has remained<br />

unchanged at $8 per unit, the marginal cost of labor has nov\' increased to<br />

$50 per unit, so that the marginal cost of each unit of overtime output is<br />

$58 per day. Because the marginal cost is higher than the average variable<br />

cost, a manager who relies on average variable cost will produce too much<br />

output.<br />

Second, n sillgle item 011 n firm's nccolllztillg ledger IIlny hnve two cOlllpollellts, only<br />

olle of which illvolves mnrgillnl cost. Suppose, for example, that a manager is trying<br />

to cut back production. She reduces the number of hours that some<br />

employees work and lays off others. But the salary of an employee who is laid<br />

off may not be an accurate measure of the marginal cost of production when<br />

cuts are made. Union contracts, for example, often require the firm to pay laidoff<br />

employees part of their salary. In this case, the marginal cost of increasing<br />

production is not the same as the savings in marginal cost when production is<br />

decreased. The savings is the labor cost after the required layoff salary has been<br />

subtracted.<br />

Third, nil opportllllity costs shollid be il1clllded ill deterlllilling IIlnrgillnl cost.<br />

Suppose a department store wants to sell children's furniture. Instead of b~ding<br />

a new selling area, the manager decides to use part of the third floor, which<br />

had been used for appliances, for the furruhlre. The marginal cost of this space<br />

is the $90 per square foot per day in profit that would have been earned had the<br />

store continued to sell appliances there. This opportwl.ity cost measure may be<br />

much greater than what the store achlally paid for that part of the building.<br />

These three guidelines can help a manager to measure marginal cost correctly.<br />

Failure to do so can cause production to be too high or too low and<br />

thereby reduce profit.<br />

8.5<br />

ASllpply Cll/'ve for a firm tells us how much output it will produce at every possible<br />

price. We have seen that competitive firms will increase output to the point<br />

at which price is equal to marginal cost but will shut down if price is below average<br />

economic cost. We have also seen that average economic cost is equal to<br />

average total cost when there are no sunk costs but equal to average variable<br />

cost when costs treated as fixed are actually amortized sunk costs. Therefore, the<br />

firm's supply curve is the portiol1 of the mnrginnl cost CIIi've thnt lies nbove the nvernge<br />

economic cost Cllrve.<br />

Figure 8.6 illustrates the short-nm supply curve for the case in wruch all fixed<br />

costs are achlally amortized sunk costs. In Hus case, for any P greater than minimum<br />

AVC, the profit-maximizing output can be read directly from the graph. At<br />

Price<br />

(dollars per<br />

unit)<br />

P2 ---------------------------------------------<br />

P=AVC - -<br />

I<br />

o<br />

q2<br />

MC<br />

Output<br />

In the short nm, the firm chooses its output so that marginal cost Me is equal to price<br />

a.s long as the firm covers its average economic cost. When all fixed costs are amortized<br />

sunk costs, the short-run supply curve is given by the crosshatched portion of<br />

the<br />

In §7.1, we explain that<br />

economic cost is the cost<br />

associated with forgone<br />

opportunities.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!