24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

158 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

risk premium Maximum<br />

amount of money that a riskaverse<br />

person will pay to<br />

avoid taking a risk<br />

Some criminologists might describe criminals as risk lovers, especially if they<br />

commit crimes despite a high prospect of apprehension and punishment Except<br />

for such special cases, huwever, few people are risk 10"ing, at least with respect<br />

to major purchases or large amounts of income or wealth.<br />

The risk premium is the maximum amount of money that a<br />

risk-averse person will pay to avoid taking a risk. In general, the magrutude of<br />

the risk premium depends on the risky alternatives that the person faces. To<br />

determine the risk premium, "lve have reproduced the utility function of Figure<br />

5.3(a) in Figure 5.4 and extended it to an income of 540,000. Recall that an<br />

expected utility of 14 is achieved by a woman \\'ho is going to take a risky job<br />

with an expected income of 520,000. This outcome is shown graphically by<br />

drawing a horizontal line to the vertical axis from point F, v{hich bisects straight<br />

line AE (thus representing an average of $10,000 and 530,000) .. But the utility<br />

level of 14 can also be achieved if the woman has a certllin income of 516,000, as<br />

shown by dropping a vertical line from point C. Thus the risk premium of 54000,<br />

given by line segment CF, is the amount of expected income (520,000 minus<br />

516,000) that she 'would give up in order to remain indifferent between the risky<br />

job and the safe one.<br />

The extent of an individual's risk aversion<br />

depends on the nature of the risk and on the person's income. Other things<br />

being equal, risk-averse people prefer a smaller variability of outcomes. We saw<br />

that vvhen there are h\'o outcomes-an income of $10,000 and an income of<br />

$30,000-the risk premium is $4000. Now consider a second risky job, involving a<br />

.5 probability of receiving an income of $40,000 and, as shown in Figure 5.4, with a<br />

utility le\"el of 20; and a .5 probability of getting an income of SO, vvith a utility level<br />

of o. The expected income is again S20,000, but the expected utility is onl;/10:<br />

Expected utility .511(50) + .511(540,000) ° + .5(20) 10<br />

Because the utility of ha\"ing a certain income of 520,000 is 16, our consumer<br />

loses 6 units of utility if she is required to accept the job. The risk premium in this<br />

case is equal to S10,000 because the utility of a certain income of S10,000 is 10:<br />

She is willing to give up 510,000 of her 520,000 expected income to ensure a certain<br />

income of S10,000 with the same le,"el of expected utilitv. Thus the (Treater<br />

the variability, the more a person is willing to pay to avoid a l:isky situati~1.<br />

We can also describe the extent<br />

of a person's ris~ a,:e.rsion .in terms of indifference curves that relate expected<br />

income to the vanablhty of ll1come, 'where the latter is measured bv the standard<br />

deviation. Figure 5.5 shows such indifference cun-es for two individuals, one<br />

who is wry risk averse and another who is only slightly risk averse. Each indifference<br />

curve shows the combinations of expected income and standard deviation<br />

of income that give the individual the same amount of utility. Observe that<br />

all of the indifference curves are up,vard sloping: Because risk is L{ndesirable, the<br />

greater the amount of risk, the greater the expected income needed to make the<br />

individual equally \'>'ell off.<br />

Figure 5.5(a) describes an individual who is highly risk averse. Observe that<br />

an increa~e in the standard deviation of income requires a large increase in<br />

e~pected .1l1come to leave this person equally well off Figure S.S(b) applies to a<br />

slIghtly nsk-averse person. In this case, a large increase in the standard deviation<br />

at income requires only a small increase in expected income.<br />

5 Choice Under Uncertainty 59<br />

In §3.1, we define an indifference<br />

curve to be all market<br />

baskets that generate the same<br />

le\'eJ of sa tis faction for a<br />

consumer<br />

Utility<br />

20<br />

18 ------------------<br />

G<br />

Expected<br />

Income<br />

Expected<br />

Income<br />

14 _____________________ AW~~<br />

Risk Premium<br />

10<br />

10 16 20 30 40<br />

Income (S1000)<br />

Standard Deviation of Income<br />

(a)<br />

Standard Deviation of Income<br />

(b)<br />

The risk premium, CF, measures the amotmt of income that an individual would give up to leave her indifferent<br />

between a risky choice and a certain one. Here, the risk premium is $4000 because a certain income of $16,000 (a!<br />

point C) gives her the same expected utility (14) as the uncertain income (a .5 probability of being at point A and a .J<br />

probability of being at point E) that has an expected value of $20,000. "",<br />

Part (a) applies :0 a pers.on who is highly risk averse: An increase in this individual's standard deviation of income<br />

~ larg~ illc:eas~ ill .expe~ted income if he is ~o ~emau: equally well off. Part (b) applies to a person who is only<br />

nsk a\ erse. An mClease ill the standard deViation of ll1come requires only a small increase in expected income

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!