24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

86 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

3 Consumer Behavior 87<br />

Other<br />

Consumption<br />

(5)<br />

p<br />

Q Education (5)<br />

When given a college trust fund that must be spent on education, the student mO\'es<br />

from A to B, a comer solution. If, however, the trust fund could be spent on other<br />

as well as education, the shldent would be better off at C.<br />

The budget line that Jane faces before being awarded the trust is given by<br />

line PQ. The trust fund expands the budget line outward as long as the full<br />

amowlt of the hmd, shown by distance PB, is spent on education. By accepting<br />

the trust fund and going to college, Jane increases her satisfaction, moving from<br />

A on indifference CUlTe LI1 to B on indifference curve LI 2·<br />

Note that B represents a comer solution because Jane's marginal rate of substihltion<br />

of other consumption for education is lower than the relative price of<br />

other consumption. Jane would prefer to spend a portion of the trust fund on<br />

other goods in addition to education. Without resh'iction on the trust hmd, she<br />

would move to C on indifference cun'e LI}, decreasing her spending on education<br />

(perhaps going to a junior college rather than a four-year college) but<br />

increasing her spending on items that she enjoys more than education.<br />

Recipients usually prefer unrestricted to restricted trusts. Restricted trusts<br />

are popular, however, because they allmv parents to control children's expendihIres<br />

in 'ways that they belie\'e are in the children's long-nm best interests.<br />

In Section 3.1, we savv how an individual's preferences could be represented by a<br />

series of indifference curves. Then in Section 3.3, we saw how preferences, gi\'en<br />

budget constraints, determine choices. Can this process be reversed If we know<br />

the choices that a consumer has made, can we determine his or her preferences<br />

¥M M<br />

_<br />

H<br />

If an individual facing budget line 11 has chosen market basket A rather than market<br />

basket B, A is revealed to be preferred to B. Likewise, the individual facing budget<br />

line 12 chooses market basket B, which is then revealed to be preferred to market<br />

basket 0, Whereas A is preferred to all market baskets in the green-shaded area, all<br />

baskets in the pink-shaded area are preferred to A.<br />

We can if we have information about a sufficient number of choices that have<br />

been made when prices and income levels varied, The basic idea is simple, If a<br />

COIlSllJller chooses one market basket over allother, and if the chosen lIIarket basket is more<br />

expensive tlUlIl the a/temative, then the conSlllller IIllist prefer the chosen market basket.<br />

Suppose that an individual, facing the budget constraint given by line 11 in<br />

Figure 3.17, chooses market basket A Let's compare A to baskets Band D.<br />

Because the individual could have purchased basket B (and all baskets below<br />

line 11) and did not, we say that A is pr~felTed to B.<br />

It might seem at first glance that we cannot make a direct comparison<br />

behveen baskets A and 0 because 0 is not on 1 1 , But suppose the relative prices<br />

of food and clothing change, so that the new budget line is 12 and the individual<br />

then chooses market basket B. Because 0 lies on budget line 12 and was not chosen,<br />

B is preferred to 0 (and to all baskets below line 12)' Because A is preferred<br />

to Band B is preferred to 0, we conclude that A is preferred to D. Furthermore,<br />

note in Figure 3.17 that basket A is preferred to all of the baskets that appear in<br />

the green-shaded areas. However, because food and clothing are" goods" rather<br />

than "bads," all baskets that lie in the pink-shaded area in the rectangle above<br />

and to the right of A are preferred to A Thus, the indifference curve passing<br />

through A must lie in the unshaded area.<br />

Given more information about choices when prices and income levels vary, we<br />

can get a better fix on the shape of the indifference cun'e. Consider Figure 3.18.<br />

Suppose that facing line 13 (which was chosen to pass through A), the individual<br />

chooses market basket E Because E was chosen even though A was equally expensive<br />

(it lies on the same budget line), E is preferred to A, as are all points in the rectangle<br />

above and to the right of E. Now suppose that facing line 14 (which passes<br />

through A), the individual chooses market basket G. Because G was chosen and<br />

A was not, G is preferred to A, as are all market baskets above arId to the right of G.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!