24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

274 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

8 Profit Maximization and Competitive Supply 275<br />

Dollars<br />

per unit of<br />

output<br />

540<br />

lMC<br />

Dollars'<br />

per unit of<br />

output<br />

Industry<br />

5<br />

To see ,·vhy all the conditions for long-run<br />

uilibrium must hold, assume that all firms have identical costs. Now consider<br />

~~lat happens if too many firms enter the u1dustry in response to an opportunity<br />

for profit. The ind~lst~y supply cun-e in Figure_8.14(b) will.shift further t~ the<br />

'oht, and price ,vIll tall below S30-say, to 52;:,. At that pnce, however, fIrms<br />

~iIllose money. As a result, some firms will exit the industry. Finns will continue<br />

to exit until the market supply curve shifts back to 52' Only when there is<br />

no incenti\-e to exit or enter can a market be in long-run equilibrium.<br />

S30<br />

(a)<br />

Output<br />

Initially the long-run equilibrium price of a product is $40 per unit, as shown in (b) as the intersection of demand<br />

curve D and supply curve 51' In (a) we see that firms earn positive profits because lona-run averaae cost reaches a<br />

. . f$ 0 0<br />

rrurumum 0: 30 (at q~). This positive profit encourages entry of new finns and causes a shift to the right in the supply<br />

Cl.m'e to 52 as shovm m (a). The long-nm equilibrium occurs at a price of $30 as shovm in (b), ,vhere each firm earns<br />

zero profit and there is no incentive to enter or exit the<br />

long-run competitive equilibrium<br />

All firms in an industry<br />

are maximizing profit, no<br />

firm has an incentiye to enter<br />

or exit, and price is such that<br />

quantity supplied equals<br />

quantity demanded<br />

When a finn earns zero economic profit, it has no incentive to exit the industry.<br />

Likewise, other finns ha\-e no special incentive to enter. A long-run competitive<br />

equilibrium occurs when three conditions hold:<br />

1. All firms in the industry are maximizing profit.<br />

2. No firm has an incentive either to enter or exit the industry because all firms<br />

are earning zero economic profit.<br />

3. The price of tl1e product is 511C11 that the qua11tit)T Sllpplied by the iI1dustry is<br />

equal to the quantity demanded by consumers.<br />

The dynamic process that leads to long-run equilibrium creates a puzzle. Firms<br />

enter the market because they hope to earn a profit, and like,·vise they exit because<br />

of economic losses. In long-run equilibrium, however, firms earn zero economic<br />

profit. vVhy does a firm enter a market knowing that it will evenhlally earn zero<br />

profit The answer is that zero economic profit represents a competitive return for<br />

the finn's inveshnent of financial capital. With zero economic profit, the finn has<br />

no incentive to go elsewhere because it carmot do better financially by doing so. If the<br />

firm happens to enter a market sufficiently early to enjoy an economic profit in the<br />

short run, so much the better. Similarly, if a firm exits an unprofitable market<br />

quickly, it can save its uwestors money. Thus the concept of long-nm equilibrium tells<br />

us the direction that firms' behavior is likelv to take. The idea of an evenhlal zeroprofit,<br />

long-rurl equilibrium should not dis~ourage a manager-it should be seen<br />

U1 a positive light, because it reflects the opporhmity to eam a competitive rehlrI1·<br />

Now suppose that all finns U1 the u1dustry<br />

do not haw identical cost curves. Perhaps one finn has a patent that lets it produce<br />

at a lower average cost than all other firms. In that case, it is consistent ,vith<br />

long-run equilibrium for that firm to earn a greater acco1llltillg profit and to enjoy<br />

a hiaher producer surplus than other finns. As long as other investors and firms<br />

cal;ot acquire the patent that lowers costs, they have no incentive to enter the<br />

industry. Com-ersely, as long as the process is particular to this product and this<br />

industry, the fortunate firm has no incentive to exit the u1dustry.<br />

The distinction between accounting profit and economic profit is important<br />

here. If the patent is profitable, other firms U1 the u1dustry will pay to use it (or<br />

attempt to buy the entire firm to acquire it). TIle increased value of the patent thus<br />

represents an opporhmity cost to the finn that holds it. It could sell the rights to the<br />

patent rather than use it. If all finns are equally efficient otherwise, the ecolloJllic<br />

profit of the firm falls to zero. However, if the firm with the patent is more efficient<br />

than other finns, then it will be earning a positive profit. But if the patent<br />

holder is otherwise less efficient, it should sell off the patent and exit the u1dushy.<br />

There are other instances in which firms<br />

earning positive accounting profit may be earning zero economic profit.<br />

Suppose, for example, that a clothing store happens to be located near a large<br />

shopping center. The additional flm·" of customers may substantially increase<br />

the store's accounting profit because the cost of the land is based on its historical<br />

cost. However, as far as economic profit is concerned, the cost of the land should<br />

reflect its opporhmity cost, which in this case is the current market value of the<br />

land. When the opportunity cost of land is included, the profitability of the<br />

dothu1g store is no higher than that of its competitors.<br />

Thus the condition that economic profit be zero is essential for the market to<br />

be in long-run equilibrium. By definition, positive economic profit represents an<br />

opportunity for investors and an incentive to enter an industry. Positive<br />

accounting profit, however, may signal that finns already in the industry possess<br />

valuable assets, skills, or ideas, which will not necessarily encourage entry.<br />

Economic Rent<br />

We have seen that some firms earn higher accounting profit than others because<br />

they have access to factors of production that are in lunited supply; these might inclUde<br />

land and natural resources, entrepreneurial skill, or other creative talent. In<br />

these sihlations what makes econOlnic profit zero in the long nm is the willu1gness<br />

of other firms to use the factors of production that are m limited supply. TIle positive<br />

accountu1g profits are therefore translated into econoJllic rellt that is earned<br />

by the scarce factors. Economic rent is what firms are willu1g to pay for an input<br />

less the muumum amOl.mt necessary to buy it. In competitive markets, in both the<br />

short and the long rW1, economic rent is often positive even though profit is zero.<br />

economic rent Amount that<br />

firms are willing to pay for an<br />

input less the minimum<br />

amount necessary to obtain it.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!