24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

296 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets 297<br />

organs. Each year, about 8000 kidneys, 20,000 corneas, and 1200 hearts<br />

h'ansplanted in the United States, but there is considerable excess demand<br />

these organs, and many potential recipients must do \\'ithout them.<br />

potential recipients die as a result<br />

To tmderstand the effects of this la,\" let's consider the supply and<br />

for kidneys. First the supply curve. Even at a price of zero (the effective<br />

under the law), donors supply about 8000 kidneys per year. But many<br />

people who need kidney transplants cannot obtain them because of a<br />

of donors. It has been estimated that 4000 more kidneys would be<br />

the price 'were $20,000. We can fit a linear supply curve to this d<br />

supply curve of the form Q a + bP. When P = 0, Q = 8000, so a = 8000.<br />

P = $20,000, Q = 12,000, so b = (12,000 8000)/20,000 = 0.2. Thus the<br />

curve is<br />

Price I 5'<br />

5-10,000<br />

30,000 D<br />

20,000<br />

Supply: QS = 8000 + 0.2P<br />

Note that at a price of $20,000, the elasticity of supply is 0.33.<br />

It is expected that at a price of $20,000, the number of kidneys ~".lllClltUI:!U.<br />

would be 12,000 per year. Like supply, demand is relatively price inelastic;<br />

reasonable estimate for the elasticity of demand at the $20,000 price is<br />

This implies the following linear demand curve:<br />

10,000 A<br />

In §2.6, we explain how to fit<br />

linear demand and supply<br />

curves from information<br />

about the equilibrium price<br />

and quantity and the price<br />

elasticities of demand and<br />

supply.<br />

Demand: QD = 16,000 - 0.2P<br />

These supply and demand curves are plotted in Figure 9.6, which shows<br />

market-clearing price and quantity of $20,000 and 12,000, respectively.<br />

Because the sale of kidneys is prohibited, supply is limited to 8000<br />

number of kidneys that people donate). This constrained supply is shown<br />

the vertical line Sf. How does this affect the welfare of kidney suppliers and<br />

recipients<br />

First consider suppliers. Those who provide kidneys fail to receive the<br />

520,000 that each kidney is worth-a loss of surplus represented by rectangle A<br />

and equal to (8000)($20,000) = $160 million. Moreover, some people who would.<br />

supply kidneys if they were paid do not These people lose an amount of sm~<br />

plus represented by triangle C, which is equal to (1/2)(4000)($20,000) = $40mi1~<br />

lion. 111erefore the total loss to suppliers is $200 million.<br />

What about recipients Presumably the law intended to treat the kidneyasa<br />

gift to the recipient. In this case, those recipients who obtain kidneys gaill rectangle<br />

A ($160 million) because they do not have to pay the $20,000 price. Those<br />

who cannot obtain kidneys lose surplus of an amOtmt given by triangle B<br />

equal to $40 million. 11us implies a net increase in the surplus of recipients<br />

$160 - $4:0 = $120 million. It also implies a deadweight loss equal to the<br />

of h'iangles Band C (i.e., 580 million).<br />

111ese estimates of the welfare effects of the policy may need adjushl1ent<br />

two reasons. First, kidneys will not necessarily be allocated to those who<br />

them most highly. If the limited supply of kidneys is partly allocated to peoplE;<br />

with valuations below $40,000, the true deadweight loss will be higher than oUT<br />

estimate. Second, with excess demand, there is no way to ensure that recipients<br />

will receive their kidneys as gifts. In practice, kidneys are often rationed 011 the<br />

basis of willingness to pay, and many recipients end up paying all or mo~t<br />

the $40,000 price that is needed to clear the market when supply is constnuned<br />

market-clearing price is $20,000; at this price, about 12,000 kidneys per year<br />

i .. would be supplied. The act effectively makes the price zero. About 8000 kidneys per<br />

are still donated; this constrained supply is shown as Sf. 111e loss to suppliers is<br />

, given by rectangle A and triangle C. If constilllers received kidneys at no cost, their<br />

would be given by rectangle A less triangle B. In practice, kidneys are often<br />

,rationed on the basis of willingness to pay, and many recipients pay most or all of the<br />

$40,000 price that clears the market when is constrained. Rectangles A and D<br />

measure the total value of when is constrained.<br />

to 8000. • A good part of the value of the kidnevs-rectanales _ 1:) A and D in the fia- 1:)<br />

me-IS then captured by hospitals and middlemen. As a result, the law reduces<br />

the surplus of recipients as well as of suppliers. 3<br />

There are, of course, arguments in favor of prohibiting the sale of organs.~<br />

One. argument st~ms from the problem of imperfect information; if people<br />

receive payment tor organs, they may hide adverse information about their<br />

health histories. This argument is probably most applicable to the sale of blood,<br />

where there is a possibility of h"ansmitting hepatitis, AIDS, or other viruses. But<br />

~~ fu:ther analyses of these efficiency costs, see Dwane L Barney and R. Larry Reynolds, "An<br />

D .omlC/Analysls at Transplant Organs," At/alltlc Ecollolllic Journal 17 (September 1989): 12-20;<br />

a~Id L Kaserman and A H Barnett, "An Economic Anah'sis of Transplant Oraans: A Comment<br />

an Extension," Atlalltic Ecollolllic Journnl19 (June 1991): 57-64; and A. Frank "'Adams III, A. H<br />

and Da\2d L Kaserman, "Markets for Organs: The Question of Supplv," COlltclIlpOral'l{<br />

FohCij, II (April 1999); 147-55 ~,<br />

"tor discussions of the strengths and weaknesses of these arguments, see Susan Rose-Ackerman,<br />

Ron:e~e~abIllty and the Theory of Property Rights," Colllllibin Lilli' Rel,icl1' 85 (June 1985): 931-69, and<br />

" ' BlaIr and DaVid L Kaserman, "The Economics and Ethics of Alternati\'e Cadaveric Oraan<br />

Policies," Ynle Joumal Oil Regulatioll 8 (Summer 1991): 403-52.<br />

'"

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!