24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

254 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

miaht compete very aaaressiveiv (as we will see in Chapter 13). The important<br />

o _ 00 _<br />

point to remember is that although firms may behave competitively in many situations,<br />

there is no simple indicator to tell us w'hen a market is highly competi_<br />

tive. Often it is necessary to analyze both the firms themselves and their strategic<br />

interactions, as we do in Chapters 12 and 13.<br />

bsidizes public television may seem public-spirited and altruistic. Yet this<br />

~uneficence is likely to be in the long-run financial interest of the firm because it<br />

;nerates good'will for the firm and its products.<br />

8.3<br />

Chapter 8 Profit Maximization and Competitive Supply 255<br />

We nm,,' turn to the analysis of profit maximization. In this section, we ask<br />

whether firms do indeed seek to maximize profit. Then in Section 8.3 \ve will<br />

describe a rule that any firm-whether in a competitive market or not-can Use<br />

to find its profit-max{Inizing output level. Then, we will consider the special<br />

case of a firm in a competitive market. We distinguish the demand CUl'\"e facing a<br />

competitive firm from the market demand curve and use this information to<br />

describe the competitive firm's profit-maximization rule.<br />

Do Firms Maximize Profit<br />

The assumption of profit maximization is frequently used in microeconomics<br />

because it predicts business behavior reasonably accurately and avoids mmecessary<br />

analytical complications. But the question of whether firms actually do seek<br />

to maximize profit has been controversial.<br />

For smaller firms managed by their owners, profit is likely to dominate<br />

almost all decisions. In larger firms, however, managers who make day-to-day<br />

decisions usually have little contact with the mvners (Le., the stockholders). As a<br />

result, owners cannot monitor the managers' behavior on a regular basis.<br />

Manaaers then have some leewav in how they run the firm and can deviate from<br />

o J_<br />

profit-maximizing behavior.<br />

Manaaers o may _ be more concerned with such aoals 0 as reyenue maximization,<br />

revenue growth, or the payment of dividends to satisfy shareholders. They<br />

miaht also be overly concerned 'with the firm's short-run profit (perhaps to eam<br />

a ;romotion or a large bonus) at the expense of its longer-run profit, even<br />

thouah lona-run profit maximization better serves the interests of the stockholdo<br />

0<br />

ers.l (We discuss the implications of differences between the incenti\'es of managers<br />

and owners in greater detail in Chapter 17.) . .<br />

Even so, managers' freedom to pursue goals other than long-run proflt maXImization<br />

is limited. If they do pursue such goals, shareholders or boards of<br />

directors can replace them, or the firm can be taken over by new mana~ement.<br />

In any case, firms that do not come close to maxirnizing profit are not likely t<br />

survive. Firms that do survive in competitive industries make long-run profit<br />

maximization one of their highest priorities. .<br />

Thus our workina assumption of profit maximization is reasonable. FIrms<br />

o ,<br />

that have been in business for a lona time are likely to care a lot about prall,<br />

o . -. that<br />

whatever else their managers may appear to be dOIng. For example, a hrm<br />

Let's begin by looking at the profit-maximizing output decision for allY firm,<br />

whether the finn operates in a perfectly competitive market or is one that can<br />

influence price. Because profit is the difference between (total) revenue and<br />

(total) cost, finding the finn's profit-maximizing output level means analyzing<br />

its revenue. Suppose that the firm's output is q, and that it obtains revenue R.<br />

This revenue is equal to the price of the product P times the number of units<br />

sold: R == Pq. The cost of production C also depends on the level of output. The<br />

firm's profit, Ti, is the difference between revenue and cost:<br />

Ti(q) = R(q) - C(q)<br />

(Here we show explicitly that 77, R, and C depend on output. Usually we will<br />

omit this reminder.)<br />

To maximize profit, the firm selects the output for which the difference<br />

between revenue and cost is the greatest. This prir1Ciple is illustrated in Figure<br />

8.1. Revenue R(q) is a curved line, which reflects the fact that the firm can sell a<br />

greater le\'el of output only by 10werir1g its price. The slope of this revenue curve<br />

Cost,<br />

Revenue,<br />

Profit<br />

(dollars per year)<br />

Clq!<br />

profit Difference behveen<br />

total revenue and total cost<br />

1 To be more exact, maximizing the market \'alue of the firm isa more appropriate goal th~n ~rf~!<br />

maximization because market value includes the stream of profIts that the fIrm earns 0\ er tIm .<br />

the stream of current and future profits that is of direct interest to the stockholdersc<br />

firm chooses output q*, so that profit, the difference AB between revenue R and<br />

C, is maximized. At that output, marginal revenue (the slope of the revenue<br />

:e) is equal to marginal cost (the slope of the cost curve).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!