24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

338 Part 3 Market Structure and Competitive Strategy<br />

The firm should increase output fron .. each plant until the incremental<br />

from the last tmit produced is zero. Start by setting incremental profit from<br />

put at Plant 1 to zero:<br />

~7T ~(PQT) _ ~Cl = 0<br />

~Ql ~Ql ~Ql<br />

Here ~(PQT)/~Ql is the revenue from producing and selling one more unit,<br />

marginal revenue, MR, for all of the firm's output. The next term, ~Cl/LlQlt<br />

marginal cost at Plant 1, Mel' We thus have MR - Mel = 0, or<br />

10 Market Power: Monopoly and Monopsony<br />

6 NO'N vve can find the profit-maximizing output levels Ql' Q2' and QT' First,<br />

the intersection of MeT with MR; that point determines total output QT'<br />

draw a horizontal line from that point on the marginal revenue curve to<br />

vertical axis; point MR* determines the firm's marginal revenue. The interctions<br />

of the marginal revenue line with Mel and Mel give the outputs Ql and<br />

se for the two plants, as in equation (10.3).<br />

Note that total output QT determines the firm's marginal revenue (and hence 1<br />

its price P*). Ql and Q2' however, determine marginal costs at each of the two<br />

plants. Because MeT was found by horizontally summing Mel and Me 2 , we<br />

know that Ql + Q2 = QT' Thus these output levels satisfy the condition that<br />

MR :::: MC l = Me2·<br />

Similarly, we can set incremental profit from output at Plant 2 to zero,<br />

MR = Mel<br />

Putting these relations together, we see that the firm should produce so that<br />

(10.3)<br />

Figure 10.6 illustrates this principle for a firm with two plants. Me1 and<br />

are the marginal cost curves for the two plants. (Note that Plant 1 has higher.<br />

marginal costs than Plant 2.) Also shown is a curve labeled MeT' This is the<br />

firm's total marginal cost and is obtained by horizontally summing Mel<br />

S/Q<br />

pure monopoly is rare. Markets in which several firms compete 'with one<br />

another are much more common. We say more about the forms this competition<br />

can take in Chapters 12 and 13. But we should explain here why each firm in a<br />

market with several firms is likely to face a downward-sloping demand curve,<br />

and, as a result, produce so that price exceeds marginal cost.<br />

Suppose, for example, that four firms produce toothbrushes, which have<br />

the market demand curve s11O"wn in Figure 10.7(a). Let's assume that these<br />

Market Demand<br />

2.00<br />

S/Q<br />

/ Demand Faced by Firm A<br />

p:<br />

1.60<br />

1.50<br />

P* ------------<br />

lAO<br />

MR*F-------~------~~----~<br />

O=AR<br />

LOO "--___ LI ___ --'-___ --L __ ::-_____ _<br />

30,000 Quantity 3,000 5,000 7,000<br />

(a) shows ~he market demand for toothbrushes. Part (b) shows the demand for toothbrushes as seen by Firm A.<br />

market pnce of $1.50, elasticity of market demand is -1.5. Firm A, however, sees a much more elastic demand<br />

D A because of competition from other firms. At a price of $1.50, Firm A's demand elasticity is - 6. Still, Firm A<br />

some monopoly power: Its profit-maximizing price is $1.50, which exceeds marginal cost.<br />

A firm with two plants maximizes profits by choosing output levels C1 and<br />

that marginal revenue MR (whidl depends on total output) equals margmal<br />

similari7 to the way. we obtained a competitive industry'S supply cun'e in Chapter 8 by<br />

. surnrnmg the margmal cost curves of the individual firms.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!