24.12.2014 Views

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

Daniel l. Rubinfeld

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

68 Part 2 Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets<br />

Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior 69<br />

M=<br />

16<br />

Clothing<br />

(units per<br />

week) 1-b<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

-6<br />

Thus the MRS at any point is equal in magnitude to the slope of the indifference<br />

curve. In Figure 3.5, for example, the MRS between points A and B is 6: The<br />

consumer is willing to give up 6 units of clothing to obtain 1 additional unit of<br />

food, Between points Band 0, however, the MRS is 4: With these quantities of<br />

food and clothing, the consumer is willing to give up only 4 units of clothina to<br />

obtain 1 additional unit of food. 0<br />

Also observe in Figure 3.5 that the MRS falls as we move down the<br />

indifference curve. This is not a coincidence. This decline in the MRS reflects an<br />

important characteristic of consumer preferences. To understand this, we will<br />

add an additional assumption regarding consumer preferences to the three that<br />

we discussed earlier in the chapter:<br />

6<br />

-b<br />

2<br />

2 3<br />

G<br />

5 Food<br />

(units per week)<br />

4. Diminishing. Illargil1.c3,Lra le_oLsubstituti on: Indifference curves are convex<br />

or bowed inward. The term cOllve .... means that the slope of the indifferen~~<br />

curve ill creases (i.e., becomes less negative) as we move down along the<br />

curve. In other words, Illl illdifferellce curve is call vex if the MRS dimillishes<br />

Il/ollg the clirve. The indifference curve in Figure 3.5 is convex. As we have<br />

seen, starting with market basket A in Figure 3.5 and moving to basket B, the<br />

MRS of food F for clothing C is ~C/.lF = - (- 6)/1 = 6, However, when<br />

we start at basket B and move from B to 0, the MRS falls to 4, If we start at<br />

basket D and move to E, the MRS is 2. Starting at E and moving to G, we get<br />

an MRS of 1. As food consumption increases, the slope of the indifference<br />

curve falls in magnitude. Thus the MRS also falls. 2<br />

marginal rate of substitution<br />

(MRS) Amount of a good<br />

that a consumer is willing to<br />

give up in order to obtain one<br />

additional unit of another<br />

good.<br />

111e slope of an indifference curve measures the consumer's marginal rate of substitution<br />

(MRS) between two goods. In this figure, the MRS behveen clothing (C) and<br />

food (F) falls from 6 (between A and B) to 4 (between B and D) to 2 (behveen D and E)<br />

to 1 (beh\'een E and G). When the MRS diminishes along an indifference curve, the<br />

curve is convex.<br />

Marginal<br />

To quantify the amount of one good that a consumer will give up to obtain more<br />

of another, we use a measure called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS).<br />

The MRS off'ood F f'or clothing C is the 1lll101lIZt of clothing tllllt II person is willillg to<br />

giue lip to obtllin one Ildditiollill lInit off'ood. Suppose, for example, the MRS is 3.<br />

This means that the consumer will give up 3 units of clothing to obtain 1 additional<br />

unit of food. If the MRS is 1/2, the consumer is willing to give up only<br />

1/2 unit of clothing. Thus, the MRS measures the mille that the individuill pillces Oil<br />

1 extm lInit of one good in terms of another.<br />

Look again at Figure 3S Note that clothing appears on the vertical axis and<br />

food on the horizontal axis. When vve describe the MRS, we must be clear about<br />

which good we are giving up and which we are getting more of. To be consistent<br />

throughout the book, we will define the MRS in terms of the alllolillt of the good 011<br />

the uerticiliaxis that the COll51l11ler is willing to give lip to Obtllill 1 extm lInit of the good<br />

on the llOri20lltlllaxis. Thus in Figure 3.5, the MRS refers to the amount of clothing<br />

that the consumer is willing to give up to obtain an additional unit of food. If we<br />

denote the cJzllIzge in clothing by .lC and the change in food by .IF, the MRS can<br />

be written as - .lC/.lF. We add the negative sign to make the marginal rate of<br />

substitution a positive number (remember that ~C is always negative; the con­<br />

SUlT1.er gives lip clothing to obtain additional food).<br />

Is it reasonable to expect indifference curves to be convex Yes. As more and<br />

more of one good is consumed, we can expect that a conSUIl1er will prefer to aive<br />

up fewer and fewer muts of a second good to get additionallmits of the fil'st ~ne.<br />

As we move down the indifference curve in Figure 3.5 and consumption of food<br />

increases, the additional satisfaction that a consumer gets from still more food will<br />

dimirush. Thus, he will give up less and less clothing to obtain additional food.<br />

Another way of describir1g this prir1ciple is to say that conSUIl1ers generally prefer<br />

balanced market baskets to market baskets that contain all of one aood and<br />

none of another. Note from Figure 3.5 that a relatively balanced market basket<br />

contairung 3 uruts of food and 6 ruuts of clothir1a (basket D) aenerates as much satisfaction<br />

as another market basket containino tmut of fool and 16 muts of clothin~<br />

(bas~et A). It follows that a balanced malket basket containing (for example) 6<br />

lUutS of tood and 8 m1its of clothing will generate a higher level of satisfaction.<br />

Perfect Substitutes and! Perfect Complements<br />

The shape of an indifference curve describes the willinaness of a consumer to<br />

~ubs~itute one good for another. An indifference curve °with a different shape<br />

unphes a different willingness to substitute. To see this principle, look at the two<br />

polar cases illustrated in Figure 3.6.<br />

Figure 3.6(a) shows Bob's preferences for apple juice and orange juice. 111ese<br />

two goods are perfect substitutes for Bob because he is entirely indifferent<br />

between having a glass of one or the other. In Hus case, the MRS of apple juice<br />

for orange juice is 1: Bob is always willir1g to h'ade 1 glass of one for 1 glass of the<br />

2 With noncom' ex preferences, the MRS increases as the amount of the (Tood measured on the hori­<br />

~ontal axis increases along any indifference curve .. This unlikely possibility might arise if one or both<br />

"oods are addICtIve. For e~ample, the wIllmgness to substitute an addictive drug for other goods<br />

mIght mcrease as the use ot the addIctl\"e drug mcreased<br />

In §2 .. 1, ,ve explain that goods<br />

are substitlltes when an<br />

increase in the price of one<br />

leads to an increase in the<br />

quantity demanded of the<br />

other.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!