29.01.2015 Views

1fAWAwx

1fAWAwx

1fAWAwx

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

spells. Because the resulting unemployment dynamics depend on the path<br />

of unemployment, not just on its current level, this phenomenon is often<br />

referred to as “hysteresis” in the rate of unemployment.<br />

The potential for hysteresis in unemployment—the economy getting<br />

stuck at high rates of unemployment for an extended period—provides a<br />

further argument for activist fiscal policy, and models that build in hysteresis<br />

effects can have large and sustained multipliers (see for example Phelps<br />

1972, Blanchard and Summers 1986, Ball 2009, and DeLong and Summers<br />

2012). Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (2013) stress the relevance<br />

of these channels to the current recovery. Their research shows that the<br />

financial crisis damaged the productive capacity of the economy, by causing<br />

a steep decline in capital accumulation, lower productivity growth, and<br />

structural damages to the labor market, and a large portion of this damage to<br />

the productive capacity stemmed from weak demand. These results suggest<br />

that under such conditions fiscal policy can continue to have a meaningful<br />

effect on output with a substantial lag.<br />

This recent work has moved far beyond the basic multiplier. It shows<br />

that fiscal and monetary policy can influence each other in substantial ways.<br />

While fiscal multipliers might be less than the basic model suggests in mild<br />

recessions and when monetary policy is unconstrained, they can be large<br />

when monetary policy is at the zero lower bound. In addition, fiscal expansion<br />

in a deep recession can have additional long-term benefits, and therefore<br />

high multipliers, by shortening spells of unemployment, minimizing the<br />

erosion of human capital, and increasing future productivity.<br />

Time Series Evidence<br />

Evaluations of fiscal effects using the structural models described<br />

above reflect the economic theory used to construct the models. The reliability<br />

of the resulting estimates therefore depends on the reliability of the<br />

underlying macroeconomic theory. A complementary approach to evaluating<br />

the effects of fiscal policy is instead to use models that rely less on economic<br />

theory and more on historical empirical evidence.<br />

The main challenge to credibly implementing this data-driven<br />

approach is using just enough theory, or finding enough independent variation<br />

in the data, to estimate the causal effect of fiscal policy on the economy:<br />

simply noting that two variables move together does not establish causality.<br />

For example, if Congress passed countercyclical fiscal policy whenever<br />

a recession loomed, a figure plotting the countercyclical policy variable<br />

and GDP growth would show that countercyclical policy occurred at the<br />

beginning of recessions. An analyst might conclude, incorrectly, that this<br />

policy caused the recession, when in fact the policy was itself caused by the<br />

142 | Chapter 3

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!