10.07.2015 Views

Work and Leisure

Work and Leisure

Work and Leisure

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

104 Chris Gratton <strong>and</strong> Peter TaylorSo it seems that Europe <strong>and</strong> Europeans are different. We pay more taxes sothat government can provide a rich <strong>and</strong> varied leisure lifestyle for its citizens.Our education system gives us the skills to appreciate <strong>and</strong> enjoy culture <strong>and</strong>leisure. And we work less so that we have the time to enjoy our leisure. As aresult, by American st<strong>and</strong>ards, we have a leisurely lifestyle that delivers agood quality of life.ConclusionIt was thought by many experts, including economists, that at the beginningof the twenty-first century we would be faced by a problem of having toomuch leisure time. However, for some countries in the world, most notably theUnited States <strong>and</strong> Britain, most people seem to be faced with decreasingleisure time. This does not, however, indicate that leisure is an inferior goodbecause there is evidence that many would prefer to trade-off some of theirincome for more leisure time. Furthermore, many people would prefer tochange the times at which they work <strong>and</strong> take leisure.Such evidence casts doubt on the validity in practice of the income/leisuretrade-off model. First, the choices are more complex (work, leisure, unpaidwork, obligated time) <strong>and</strong> unpaid work <strong>and</strong> obligated time are not necessarilyconstant. Second, time allocations involve both the individual <strong>and</strong> theemployer; <strong>and</strong> the individual’s preferences are often overridden by employerdecisions. Third, there are substantial labour market rigidities which preventa continuity of choice for individual workers – they are faced with imperfectoptions such as working overtime to retain credibility in the workplace; <strong>and</strong>working unsocial hours or not at all. Fourth, market work, particularly overtimeworking, is not always compensated directly by an hourly wage rate. Theincome/leisure trade-off model is therefore too unconstrained – it assumestoo much of the labour market.The outcome of the constrained labour market is that many individuals inthe UK, United States <strong>and</strong> Japan work for longer hours than they wouldideally want, <strong>and</strong> possibly at times of the day <strong>and</strong> week that they would prefernot to work. But there are not feasible alternatives to this working arrangement<strong>and</strong> it is therefore a ‘second best’ solution which people get used to. Itbecomes a cultural <strong>and</strong> behavioural norm which is difficult to reverse. Bothlabour market rigidities <strong>and</strong> individual expectations conspire, therefore, toprevent the UK, United States <strong>and</strong> Japan approaching European norms inwork <strong>and</strong> leisure time allocations.As we become increasingly affluent, time becomes a more valuable commodity.Yet in the richest societies, time has become increasingly scarce aslong working hours, particularly for those earning most in the labour market,severely constrain the leisure time in which to enjoy this increasing affluence.The end result is the lack of correspondence of st<strong>and</strong>ard economic indicators

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!