27.12.2012 Views

The 1995/1996 Household Income, Expenditure - (PDF, 101 mb ...

The 1995/1996 Household Income, Expenditure - (PDF, 101 mb ...

The 1995/1996 Household Income, Expenditure - (PDF, 101 mb ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

III. 7<br />

in the measurement of poverty,11 is but one characteristic of a complex<br />

quality of life unique to each environment. Whether or not an effort is<br />

made to include public goods in welfarist or in society-based<br />

measurements is beside the point; the linkage between the existence of<br />

public goods and their usage (by extension, a higher living standard) is<br />

not assured.<br />

<strong>The</strong> unit of analysis - individual versus household - conditions<br />

the measurement of poverty. Individual data may be preferred to<br />

household data for their information richness, but sometimes the<br />

assumptions required to make inferences using individual data are<br />

unreasonable. For example, in comparing the poverty of individuals<br />

based on calorie intakes, one assumes that an individual of a certain<br />

sex, age, height and weight requires a certain nu<strong>mb</strong>er of completenutrition<br />

calories per day, and that this requirement (Le., level of<br />

activity), and even metabolic rate, stays constant. However, activity<br />

levels themselves can depend on calorie consumption, an interaction<br />

which greatly confounds the equation for nutrition requirements. Even<br />

after controlling for the higher share of food expenditures typical of<br />

the poor, the correlation between food energy consumption and<br />

expenditures can be different across areas. <strong>The</strong> food-energy method<br />

alone is deficient for constructing poverty indices because food energy<br />

intake also varies with income levels, over time and across areas. <strong>The</strong><br />

mere fact that a certain diet meets the requirements for a functioning<br />

human body is irrelevant to whether such a diverse diet will be sought<br />

after, or even less likely, available in the market.<br />

IH.D Poverty and <strong>Household</strong> <strong>Expenditure</strong> Data<br />

In the empirical section which follows, I use income and<br />

expenditure data from Egypt's HIECS to make provisional inferences<br />

about poverty and inequality.<br />

Before choosing an indicator to represent economic rank,<br />

statistical integrity depends on the proper sampling design. For<br />

economic information to characterize households in a valid way: 1)<br />

households should be selecte?z randomly, such that each has an equal<br />

probability of being sampled; and 2) households should be selected<br />

independently of one another. Discounting anu<strong>mb</strong>er of potential nonsampling<br />

errors, these are the minimal measures taken to assure that<br />

estimates about the population using sample units will be unbiased (Le.,<br />

on target within a certain bound) and have smooth, well-defined<br />

distributions. Another concern, more a prescription than a rule, is that<br />

"enough" households are sampled so that the law of large nu<strong>mb</strong>ers<br />

applies. With household expenditure survey sampling, there is always a<br />

concern that the sample does not cover every household, that despite<br />

11 See Deaton (1988) for an exposition on assigning values to public<br />

goods of variable quality.<br />

12 If stratified random sampling is used, the within-stratum selection<br />

should be random.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!