27.12.2012 Views

The 1995/1996 Household Income, Expenditure - (PDF, 101 mb ...

The 1995/1996 Household Income, Expenditure - (PDF, 101 mb ...

The 1995/1996 Household Income, Expenditure - (PDF, 101 mb ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

VI.?<br />

notoriously difficult to regulate. Moreover, tenants evade the laws by<br />

subletting to friends. It has been estimated that there are some 12 million<br />

landlord/tenant lawsuits pending in the courts, and that by the year 2000<br />

there might be 19 million. J <strong>The</strong> nu<strong>mb</strong>er of judges trying these cases has 6<br />

remained stagnant, and rental cases take up to 8 years to come to a decision.<br />

One of the results of Sadat's Open Door (infitah) economic policy ­<br />

beginning roughly in 1974 - was a large increase in private sector investment<br />

in housing. <strong>The</strong> 1970p were boom years as the private sector took command of<br />

housing construction. Land, building materials and construction labor prices<br />

rose rapidly. However, housing investment was not intended for easing<br />

population pressures on inhabitable space during the decade after 1973. As<br />

the population of Cairo nearly doubled, from 6 million to 10 million, Waterbury<br />

(1983) estimates that three-quarters of all dwellings constructed during the<br />

period were intended for luxury use.<br />

By 1992 housing investment had recovered to 10.9% of total investment<br />

in the economy, and 95% of this came from the private sector. For the<br />

government's Third 5-Year Plan (1992-1997), the private sector was expected<br />

J Statement of former World Bank resident advisor in Egypt Marcelo<br />

Cuigale.<br />

6 Serageldin (1993).<br />

7 Between 1960 and 1976 the public sector provided around one-third (UN<br />

(Habitat), p. 15) of housing construction, mainly substandard (or "popular")<br />

housing to be provided at greatly subsidized rates. Legislation for informal<br />

communities emphasized the government's commitment to equity and<br />

participation. Law 135 of 1981 officially recognized slum areas as legitimate<br />

and permanent settlements to be incorporated into the formal planning<br />

process, with associated infrastructure enhancements. Law 31 of 1984<br />

established procedures for legalizing land tenure in slum areas (Cooperative<br />

Housing Foundation, 1988). <strong>The</strong> state had, by that time, established its<br />

opinion that private, individual ownership of land - especially for the poorer<br />

segments - was the most secure and respectable tenure form, and therefore<br />

the most likely form for encouraging households to invest. It also provided a<br />

mechanism for cost recovery from slum upgrading. However, the state would<br />

eventually reverse its support for tenure legalization as obligations to provide<br />

infrastructure became overwhelming. A very detailed study of informal<br />

communities in Cairo and Beni Suef is found in Abt Associates, (1982).<br />

B Districts around Cairo have seen the largest land value increases.<br />

Unimproved land in Nasser City today costs approximately 7,000 £E per square<br />

meter, and upwards of 10,000 £E per square meter in Zamalek. Land in<br />

Heliopolis and Ma'adi is only marginally cheaper. Overall building costs per<br />

square meter have risen accordingly. As quoted by Dr. Milad Hanna,<br />

professor emeritus of construction engineering at Ain Shams University, Cairo,<br />

in Essam el Din (1994), pp. 15-16, the cost of constructing new popular<br />

housing is about 160 £E per square meter, 200-400 £E for "above average"<br />

housing, and 1,000-2,000 £E for luxury housing.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!