04.06.2014 Views

LITIGATING SOCIO-ECONOMIC RIGHTS IN SOUTH AFRICA - PULP

LITIGATING SOCIO-ECONOMIC RIGHTS IN SOUTH AFRICA - PULP

LITIGATING SOCIO-ECONOMIC RIGHTS IN SOUTH AFRICA - PULP

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The structural interdict 185<br />

officials and departments or spheres of government, each with<br />

different motives and goals to achieve. 104<br />

The model has, however, been criticised as encouraging<br />

perpetuation of the case and indefinite involvement of the court. This<br />

is in addition to sacrificing reasoned decision making on the part of<br />

the court. According to Fiss: 105<br />

The drive for settlement knows no bounds and can result in a consent<br />

decree even in … [structural litigation], that is, even when a court finds<br />

itself embroiled in a continuing struggle between the parties or must<br />

reform a bureaucratic organisation. The parties may be ignorant of the<br />

difficulties ahead or optimistic about the future, or they may simply<br />

believe that they can get more favorable terms through a bargained-for<br />

agreement. Soon, however, the inevitable happens: One party returns to<br />

court and asks the judge to modify the decree, either to make it more<br />

effective or less stringent. But the judge is at a loss: He has no basis for<br />

assessing the request. He cannot, to use Cardozo's somewhat<br />

melodramatic formula, easily decide whether the ‘dangers, once<br />

substantial, have become attenuated to a shadow’, because, by<br />

definition, he never knew the dangers. 106<br />

It should be noted, however, that Fiss’s criticism is based on<br />

erroneous assumptions. Some of these assumptions are motivated by<br />

the purpose of his article, namely, to criticise models of litigation that<br />

encourage alternative dispute resolution in the place of court<br />

determinations. Structural litigation does not, however, fall in this<br />

class of litigation. Structural litigation is conducted with clear<br />

appreciation of the fact that the litigation implicates interests beyond<br />

the interests of parties. This is a fact that Fiss ignores: He trivialises<br />

litigation by reducing its social function ‘to one of resolving private<br />

disputes’. 107 Fiss also ignores the fact that structural litigation is<br />

always opened up to persons not originally parties to the litigation and<br />

allows them to bring to the fore their interests. The judge remains<br />

conscious of these interests and reserves the right to reject<br />

settlements that sideline them. Fiss also does not understand that the<br />

continued involvement of the judge in the litigation is motivated by<br />

the desire to stop a systemic violation rather than the protection of<br />

the interests of the parties.<br />

Furthermore, Fiss assumes that the adversarial litigation process<br />

is the only possible method of preserving a reasoned decision-making<br />

process. 108 Reasoned decision making could still be preserved even<br />

when the order is a negotiated one; the judge could begin by laying<br />

104<br />

Note (n 68 above) 434.<br />

105 O Fiss ‘Against settlement’ (1984) 93 Yale Law Journal 1073.<br />

106 Fiss (n 105 above) 1083 (footnotes excluded).<br />

107<br />

Fiss (n 105 above) 1085.<br />

108 Sturm (n 63 above) 1400-1401.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!