22.10.2013 Views

Effectiveness and Economic Impact of Tax Incentives in the SADC ...

Effectiveness and Economic Impact of Tax Incentives in the SADC ...

Effectiveness and Economic Impact of Tax Incentives in the SADC ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECONOMICS OF HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION 6-11<br />

that <strong>the</strong> country’s important garment sector has paid little tax because <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come-shift<strong>in</strong>g<br />

strategies ra<strong>the</strong>r than fundamentally weak pr<strong>of</strong>its. Where such practices are rampant, <strong>the</strong><br />

domestic tax rate matters little.<br />

Few <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> countries have strong statutory measures <strong>and</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrative capacity to<br />

deal with abusive transfer pric<strong>in</strong>g, th<strong>in</strong> capitalization schemes, tax dodges through controlled<br />

foreign entities (CFEs), or o<strong>the</strong>r forms <strong>of</strong> aggressive avoidance through <strong>in</strong>ternational channels.<br />

On CFEs, only 5 Member States—Lesotho, Mauritius, Namibia, South Africa <strong>and</strong> Tanzania—<br />

have adopted residence-based tax systems that could br<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> domestic tax<br />

net. Regional <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational cooperation could be very useful <strong>in</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g both <strong>the</strong><br />

legal provisions <strong>and</strong> audit systems that are needed to fight potentially huge revenue losses<br />

through <strong>in</strong>ternational tax plann<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

COMPETITION WITHIN <strong>SADC</strong><br />

With<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> region, a few cases <strong>of</strong> head-to-head tax competition have been widely<br />

reported, such as <strong>the</strong> Ramatex example <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6-2. 88 Undoubtedly many o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments, which do not make <strong>the</strong> headl<strong>in</strong>es, have crossed borders to take advantage <strong>of</strong><br />

lower taxes or weaker tax adm<strong>in</strong>istration. At <strong>the</strong> policy level, some tax <strong>in</strong>centive programs<br />

have explicitly been <strong>in</strong>troduced as a response to tax competition from o<strong>the</strong>r countries <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

region <strong>and</strong> elsewhere. For example, <strong>the</strong> recent <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> full tax exemptions for EPZ<br />

enterprises <strong>in</strong> Zambia was motivated <strong>in</strong> part by a concern to match <strong>in</strong>centives available <strong>in</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r AGOA-eligible countries. 89 In some <strong>in</strong>stances, tax <strong>in</strong>centives may even have been<br />

motivated by a desire to undercut tax rates <strong>in</strong> a neighbor<strong>in</strong>g country. None<strong>the</strong>less, most tax<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive programs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> region appear to be driven by a legitimate desire to create an<br />

attractive <strong>in</strong>vestment environment, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a deliberate <strong>in</strong>tent to deprive o<strong>the</strong>r Member<br />

States <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>and</strong> revenue.<br />

Whatever <strong>the</strong> motivation for tax competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>, <strong>the</strong> most important question is<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> effects on regional development are positive or negative. In <strong>the</strong>ory, tax<br />

competition could promote development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> entire region—despite <strong>the</strong> adverse side-effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> tax <strong>in</strong>centives—if <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives attract a large amount <strong>of</strong> new <strong>in</strong>vestment. In this scenario<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is little reason to pursue restra<strong>in</strong>ts on tax competition. But this is not a realistic scenario.<br />

The preponderance <strong>of</strong> evidence (as reviewed <strong>in</strong> chapters 2 <strong>and</strong> 3) <strong>in</strong>dicates that tax <strong>in</strong>centives<br />

rarely <strong>in</strong>duce a strong <strong>in</strong>vestment response, whereas <strong>the</strong>y do impair revenue mobilization <strong>and</strong><br />

reduce economic efficiency. Hence, <strong>the</strong> operational premise is that unrestra<strong>in</strong>ed tax<br />

88 Ano<strong>the</strong>r widely cited example is <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hyundai factory <strong>in</strong> Botswana, which went <strong>in</strong>to liquidation <strong>in</strong><br />

2000. The basic cause was mismanagement <strong>and</strong> probable fraud, but <strong>the</strong> company’s demise was precipitated<br />

by a decision by South Africa to get tough on what it viewed as tax abuse. Sources: James (2003) <strong>and</strong><br />

Kebonang (2001).<br />

89 Accord<strong>in</strong>g to a well-<strong>in</strong>formed source <strong>in</strong> Zambia (<strong>in</strong> private communication) <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

new EPZ regime <strong>in</strong> Zambia have been companies that were already <strong>in</strong> existence <strong>and</strong> pay<strong>in</strong>g taxes.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!