30.10.2012 Views

Public Management and Administration - Owen E.hughes

Public Management and Administration - Owen E.hughes

Public Management and Administration - Owen E.hughes

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

analysis has declined as a framework by being overtaken by an even more rigorous<br />

rational model of economics. The key theoretical cornerstones of the public<br />

management approach are private management <strong>and</strong> economics, particularly economics<br />

of the microeconomic or public choice kind. This goes a stage further<br />

than the rational models of policy analysis, by declaring the good to be maximized<br />

by those involved to be economic utility, <strong>and</strong> deriving policy from there.<br />

It is arguable whether the increased use of economics in public policy-making<br />

is part of formal policy analysis or something separate. Given that public policy<br />

people came from political science, it may be quite separate <strong>and</strong> belong to a<br />

quite different intellectual history.<br />

A faulty model of science<br />

<strong>Public</strong> Policy <strong>and</strong> Policy Analysis 125<br />

A more controversial criticism, perhaps, is of the scientific basis used for policy<br />

analysis. Of course, any exercise aiming to be scientific must have a conception<br />

of the kind of science it aims to follow. There is reason to believe that<br />

public policy analysis is based on a faulty, or at least old-fashioned, model of<br />

science. It was mentioned earlier that the derivation of empirical methods from<br />

those of political science was both a strength <strong>and</strong> a weakness. The strength was<br />

that techniques for gathering data were well recognized, most often by sample<br />

survey. Ways of processing data through computer software became readily<br />

available, <strong>and</strong> what was being done under the name of policy analysis was a<br />

slight extension of political science methods into areas of policy. However, this<br />

also meant a reliance on the same theory of science used in political science<br />

during the 1960s <strong>and</strong> 1970s.<br />

A clue to the problem this engenders can be gained from the third of the scientific<br />

skills mentioned earlier from the work of Putt <strong>and</strong> Springer (1989, p. 24).<br />

This was ‘information-analysis skills guide the analyst in drawing conclusions<br />

from empirical evidence’. This points to a key problem, not only in policy<br />

analysis, but in behavioural political science from where its theories derive.<br />

A large part of the philosophy of science in the second half of the twentieth<br />

century was concerned with showing that data do not lead to conclusions, that<br />

such inductive science is inherently flawed (Popper, 1965). Most social science<br />

from the very beginnings of collection of data or sample surveys has been<br />

expressly inductive, that is, based on the idea that from gathering masses of<br />

information, inferences can be made. As Popper <strong>and</strong> others have argued, this<br />

cannot be done in the natural sciences, so it follows that a social science based<br />

on inductive processes is also gravely flawed.<br />

Despite criticism (for example, deLeon, 1997) a major part of the success of<br />

economic public policy in recent years is that it is expressly deductive, that is,<br />

based on theory leading to predictions. If evidence for those predictions can be<br />

found, it supports the theory. The theory is never proven, but can st<strong>and</strong> because

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!