07.11.2014 Views

Company Valuation Under IFRS : Interpreting and Forecasting ...

Company Valuation Under IFRS : Interpreting and Forecasting ...

Company Valuation Under IFRS : Interpreting and Forecasting ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Company</strong> valuation under <strong>IFRS</strong><br />

Whichever choice we make about how to treat tax shelters, however, there is no<br />

doubt that since we are treating the tax shelter as an item to be adjusted for in the<br />

discount rate (via a net of tax cost of debt), we should not also be taking it into<br />

account in the cash flows that we discount. To do so would clearly be doublecounting.<br />

So when we calculate free cash flow we do so by restating the cash<br />

flows as if the company had no debt in its balance sheet. We discount deleveraged<br />

free cash flow. This is true whether we apply a single WACC, or whether we<br />

value the unleveraged assets <strong>and</strong> the tax shelter separately, as in an APV analysis.<br />

Turning to the forecasts of economic profit <strong>and</strong> cash flow, notice a number of<br />

points relating to the calculation.<br />

• The first is that, because we want unleveraged free cash flows, we start not<br />

with pre-tax profits but with EBIT.<br />

• Secondly, the calculation of tax is a notional one. It is what the tax would<br />

have been in the event that we were not in fact going to be creating tax<br />

shelters through the payment of interest. Tax in our forecast profit <strong>and</strong> loss<br />

account is in fact lower than the tax shown here, <strong>and</strong> the difference is the tax<br />

shelter that the company will create if it carries the levels of debt that we are<br />

projecting. As with our actual forecast, we add back amortisation of goodwill<br />

into taxable profit, so the notional tax charge is arrived at by multiplying<br />

EBITA by the marginal rate of taxation.<br />

• Thirdly, we would include as part of our NOPAT those provisions for which<br />

we want to pay (deferred taxation, for example), because we do not believe<br />

that they represent a real accrual of liability. The reason for including them<br />

in the NOPAT, rather than putting them alongside depreciation will become<br />

apparent when we move on the discussing the economic profit calculation of<br />

value. Clearly, where we put them in a DCF calculation will make no<br />

difference to the calculation of free cash flow.<br />

• Fourthly, the remaining items (comprising depreciation <strong>and</strong> amortisation,<br />

capital expenditure <strong>and</strong> change in non-cash working capital) can<br />

conveniently be netted off against one another to derive a figure for net<br />

investment. This is the extent to which the company grows its balance sheet<br />

size from one period to the next.<br />

So free cash flow can either be thought of as unleveraged cash flow from<br />

operations less investment, or, much more usefully, as NOPAT minus net<br />

investments: profit less the proportion of profit that we have to plough back into<br />

the business to fund future growth. The reason why this is a much better way to<br />

look at the problem is that we have a formula for retentions, which we discussed<br />

in Chapter one. It is that retentions must equal projected growth divided by<br />

projected returns on incremental capital.<br />

204

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!