07.11.2014 Views

Company Valuation Under IFRS : Interpreting and Forecasting ...

Company Valuation Under IFRS : Interpreting and Forecasting ...

Company Valuation Under IFRS : Interpreting and Forecasting ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Chapter Two – WACC – Forty years on<br />

What is happening here? We do not get consistent value at all. The sum of the<br />

parts is bigger than the whole, which is not what we want to see. The reason is<br />

that in dividing by ‘k-g’ the impact on values is not linear as we increase ‘g’. It<br />

will have a disproportionately large impact when applied to smaller values of k.<br />

This is very unsatisfactory, <strong>and</strong> illustrates an equally important truth about the<br />

original Miller <strong>and</strong> Modigliani analysis to the fact that it was based on a tax-free<br />

<strong>and</strong> default-free world. It was also premised on a no-growth world. Techniques<br />

for building tax <strong>and</strong> default risk into the original framework have been known<br />

<strong>and</strong> used for years. But the significance of the impact of growth on valuation has<br />

not been similarly emphasised, which is very odd since its potential impact on<br />

valuations is far greater, <strong>and</strong> most valuation models do assume constant growth<br />

after a forecast period.<br />

Our approach to the practical calculation of discount rates is therefore going to<br />

differ from that conventionally followed in text-books, since we shall take pains<br />

to think through the implications of all of our actions on growing, not merely on<br />

static, streams of cash.<br />

The customary practitioners’ approach, unfortunately, is to use a theoretical<br />

structure that works perfectly in a static world, <strong>and</strong> then to misapply it to a<br />

growing one.<br />

Unfortunately, the result is systematic overvaluation, of the sort illustrated in<br />

Exhibit 2.13.<br />

So as we build tax shelters <strong>and</strong> default risk into our discount rates we must try to<br />

establish an approach that is robust when applied to growth companies. It must<br />

be said at this point that the authors claim no originality with respect to the<br />

analysis, except, perhaps, to the manner of presentation. The bibliography<br />

provides references in which all of the theory has been presented, but perhaps<br />

because of its complexity it has not yet entered commercial practice. That is what<br />

we aim to change.<br />

4. Leverage <strong>and</strong> the cost of equity<br />

Let us return to Exhibit 2.12 for a moment. Because we are in a world with no<br />

default risk, the cost of debt does not change, <strong>and</strong> should be equivalent to a risk<br />

free interest rate. The redemption yield on a long term government bond is often<br />

used as a proxy. As the gearing changes, the cost of equity changes, so that the<br />

value of the company remains unchanged. The formula for the cost of equity<br />

under the st<strong>and</strong>ard Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is as follows:<br />

37

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!