11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Recent Declines in the <strong>Saving</strong>s Rate 125<br />

a positive association between growth and government saving, and the government<br />

saving in turn should reduce to some extent private saving (equation (4.5)).<br />

This suspicion is confirmed by the results in line 3, in which we add the fiscal<br />

variable, government surplus. In line 3, the growth coefficient rises to 1.76, a value<br />

close to that <strong>of</strong> line 1. These estimates <strong>of</strong> g are <strong>of</strong> interest for several reasons. First,<br />

in the estimate, lines 2 and 3 are broadly confirmed by all the other results presented<br />

in table 4.3. The estimates fall predominantly between 1.5 and 1.8 with<br />

very few, usually explainable, exceptions, as indicated below. Second, it is consistent<br />

with the results reported in various other contributions beginning with my<br />

1970 paper. Third, this estimate is broadly consistent with the value suggested by<br />

the LCH. As we have seen in equation (4.3b), the LCH implies a non-linear relation<br />

between the saving ratio and g. In our tests we have approximated (4.3b)<br />

linearly:<br />

s = f( g)@ a+<br />

bg<br />

The slope b <strong>of</strong> this approximation might be expected close to f ¢ (ḡ ), the slope<br />

<strong>of</strong> (4.3b) <strong>com</strong>puted around the mean. By differentiation <strong>of</strong> (4.3b), the slope at<br />

any value <strong>of</strong> g is found to be:<br />

f¢( g)= d¢ ( 1-a) ( d¢+<br />

g)<br />

where:<br />

d¢= d -ra<br />

2<br />

Modigliani and Brumberg, using simulation, found that (1 - a) could be placed<br />

in the neighborhood <strong>of</strong> 0.3, and d¢ at around 0.07. The estimates have since been<br />

broadly supported by direct time series estimated, e.g. for the US (Ando and<br />

Modigliani [3]; Modigliani and Sterling [17]), and for Italy (Modigliani and Jappelli<br />

[16]), though the estimates <strong>of</strong> d have sometimes been on the low side. Hence<br />

the slope <strong>of</strong> (4.3b) at the mean value <strong>of</strong> g, which is around four percent can be<br />

placed at 1.7 for d¢ =0.07 (1.8 if d¢ =0.06), quite consistent with our estimates<br />

<strong>of</strong> the slope.<br />

In line 3 <strong>of</strong> table 4.3 the government surplus, GS, appears with a significant<br />

negative sign, implying that private saving is reduced by government saving. This<br />

result is consistent with Barro and LCH, though it rejects the traditional Keynesian<br />

formulation. The difference between LCH and Ricardian equivalence is in<br />

the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the coefficient. If l were 1 as asserted by Barro, then from (4.5a)<br />

the absolute value <strong>of</strong> the coefficient <strong>of</strong> GS should be 1 - f(g) = 0.86 in the sample,<br />

which measures the long-run propensity to save, or somewhat less, if we adjusted<br />

for the effect <strong>of</strong> deficit on private saving. The actual coefficient <strong>of</strong> GS is only<br />

0.40. With a standard error <strong>of</strong> the coefficient <strong>of</strong> 0.11, the actual coefficient is seen

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!