11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The Keynesian Gospel According to Modigliani 347<br />

employment in those industries that produce the goods they want to consume,<br />

and so on. (It is necessary to clarify that this identity is valid only in a closed<br />

economy, without a government with tax power, public expenditure, or public<br />

saving. But the identity is easily generalized—see below.)<br />

V The Under-Employment Equilibrium—Synthesis<br />

V.1 The Four Quadrants Analysis<br />

Our remaining task is to show how the interaction <strong>of</strong> the four basic blocks produces<br />

a series <strong>of</strong> results which are typically Keynesian and anti-classic, including<br />

the crucial result, namely the demonstration <strong>of</strong> the existence <strong>of</strong> stable<br />

underemployment equilibria, such as that illustrated by X* in figure 15.3. I<br />

propose to develop my argument in graphical form relying on a construction<br />

known as the four quadrant analysis. It is a bit cumbersome but in my view very<br />

helpful for a solid understanding <strong>of</strong> the argument. The four quadrants are needed<br />

to ac<strong>com</strong>modate the four variables <strong>of</strong> the model, In<strong>com</strong>e X, Investment I, <strong>Saving</strong><br />

S, and the Interest Rate r.<br />

In principle, all <strong>of</strong> these variables are measured in real terms, but because <strong>of</strong><br />

the maintained assumption that prices are rigid (in the sense that they do not<br />

respond to the remaining variables), real variables are indistinguishable from<br />

nominal. (This holds also for the interest rate, since fix-prices excludes expectations<br />

<strong>of</strong> inflation or deflation.) The four variables are measured along the four<br />

semi-axes that extend outward from the origin, as shown in the graph. Thus X is<br />

measured along the vertical axis extending upward from the origin; r is measured<br />

along to the horizontal axis, extending right-ward from the origin; and similarly<br />

I and S are measured along the remaining two semi-axes. As a result we end up<br />

with four quadrants that on the graph are labeled, counterclockwise, I to IV.<br />

V.2 In<strong>com</strong>e Depends on Investment<br />

We begin our analysis by utilizing quadrant III, IV, and I to establish that output<br />

is determined not by the classical “capacity to produce” but by the rate <strong>of</strong> investment<br />

I (or equivalently, by aggregate demand C + I). Quadrant III gives a graphical<br />

representation <strong>of</strong> the last block (section IV.4) to the effect that in equilibrium,<br />

investment must equal saving. This relation is readily represented by means <strong>of</strong><br />

the straight line through the origin <strong>of</strong> slope one. It says that to any rate <strong>of</strong> investment’<br />

say I* in the figure, there corresponds a saving rate <strong>of</strong> equal amount. S*<br />

on the S axis <strong>of</strong> quadrant III.<br />

We next move to quadrant IV, in which we graph the saving function <strong>of</strong> block<br />

3, which describes the relation between S and in<strong>com</strong>e X, measured on the

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!