11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

252 Unemployment and Monetary Policy in the European Union<br />

The final out<strong>com</strong>e <strong>of</strong> the process is an “equilibrium” in which the money<br />

market—as well as other markets with flexible prices—clear, but the labor market<br />

may end up with an excess supply because there is not enough demand for output<br />

to absorb the full-employment labor supply. But it will still be in Keynesian equilibrium,<br />

for with wage rigidity, the excess supply will not cause wages to adjust<br />

further. (In the case <strong>of</strong> an excess demand for labor, nominal wage rigidity could<br />

only be transitory and eventually result in higher wages and prices, which would<br />

reduce demand along the lines <strong>of</strong> the traditional model.)<br />

The essence <strong>of</strong> the Keynesian Revolution is that the money market is cleared—<br />

i.e. the demand for money is brought into equality with the Central Bank determined<br />

money supply—not through an imaginary high flexibility <strong>of</strong> wages, but<br />

through movements in unemployment and interest rates.<br />

4.2 Nominal Wage Rigidity versus Real Money Supply<br />

It has been argued that the market failure in this case reflects the rigidity <strong>of</strong> wages<br />

and prices that do not respond to the excess supply. But when unemployment is<br />

due to nominal wage rigidity, it is just as correct to conclude that it reflects a<br />

shortage <strong>of</strong> real money supply. For if the equilibrium could be re-established by<br />

an x percent decline in nominal wages, then to the extent that nominal wages are<br />

truly rigid up to a neighborhood <strong>of</strong> full employment, equilibrium could equally<br />

be re-established by an x percent expansion <strong>of</strong> the real money supply, whether<br />

by a fall in prices <strong>of</strong> a rise in the nominal money supply, or and <strong>com</strong>bination <strong>of</strong><br />

the two.<br />

4.3 Nominal Wage Rigidity, A Source for Concern or an<br />

Opportunity for Improved Stabilization?<br />

The hypothesis that nominal wages were rigid, or very sluggish, was widely<br />

accepted in the early postwar period. It was initially a source <strong>of</strong> concern<br />

about economic stability. For clearly, the real money supply required for full<br />

employment could be expected to vary over time as a result <strong>of</strong> parameter shifts<br />

and other shocks. But with rigid prices, there was no mechanism to ensure<br />

that the real money supply would tend to move toward the appropriate level;<br />

hence the danger <strong>of</strong> significant discrepancies and corresponding movements in<br />

unemployment.<br />

However, there soon was a more fundamental shift to optimism as it was realized<br />

that, if wages are prevailingly rigid, the real money supply could be readily<br />

controlled by the simple operation <strong>of</strong> changing the nominal money stock to<br />

ac<strong>com</strong>modate demand. Hence the exhilarating feeling, lasting through the 1960s<br />

and early 1970s, that the problem <strong>of</strong> unemployment had largely been brought<br />

under control, and that there was an important task for the macroeconomist in

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!