11.11.2014 Views

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

"Life Cycle" Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate ... - Arabictrader.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The Chinese <strong>Saving</strong> Puzzle 195<br />

marked with diamonds at the top <strong>of</strong> the graph is once again the observed saving<br />

rate. The curve that hugs it closely is the saving ratio <strong>com</strong>puted from the second<br />

period equation, III.3, that is fitted to data from 1978 to 2000. It is apparent that<br />

these <strong>com</strong>puted values fit the actual out-<strong>of</strong>-sample data from 1953 to 1978<br />

remarkably well, with moderate underestimation in 1962 to 1964.<br />

On the basis <strong>of</strong> this result it seems justified to conclude that the LCH model<br />

applies to the entire period with reasonably stable parameter estimates, despite<br />

the very notable changes in the underlying economy.<br />

The third curve shown in figure 6.7 is an analogous test <strong>of</strong> stability <strong>of</strong> coefficients<br />

for the traditional Keynesian linear model. That is, we fit this model to the<br />

years 1978–2000, and find that this fit is bearably good though it misses the later<br />

decline. When we use the parameter estimates from the second period to <strong>com</strong>pute<br />

the first period saving ratio, the result is a total failure; if saving were controlled<br />

by in<strong>com</strong>e the rise would have been much faster and there would have been a lot<br />

<strong>of</strong> “dis-saving” with the very low initial in<strong>com</strong>e. But the observed behavior is<br />

accounted for when Keynesian in<strong>com</strong>e is replaced by LCH variables, in<strong>com</strong>e<br />

growth, and population structure.<br />

5.2 Comparison with Earlier Studies—A Survey<br />

There are two major studies <strong>of</strong> which we are aware that have endeavored to test<br />

the LCH and estimate its parameters. First, Modigliani (1970) used a sample <strong>of</strong><br />

36 countries for which data were available from the UN Yearbook <strong>of</strong> National<br />

Account Statistics to test whether cross-country variations in the saving ratio<br />

could be accounted for by differences in growth rates and demographic structure,<br />

as hypothesized by LCH, instead <strong>of</strong> by differences in per-capita in<strong>com</strong>e according<br />

to the traditional view. This sample, which includes countries <strong>of</strong> quite varied<br />

backgrounds, is referred to hereafter as Cross I.<br />

The second essay is Modigliani (1990) (hereafter Cross II), which used a<br />

sample <strong>of</strong> 21 OECD countries for a cross-country test <strong>of</strong> the forces accounting<br />

for the remarkable decline in the average saving ratio from 17 percent in the<br />

period 1960–70 to 10 percent in 1981–87, and it included inflation among the<br />

explanatory variables. The major conclusions from a <strong>com</strong>parison <strong>of</strong> the present<br />

study with the previous two are summarized as follows.<br />

5.2.1 Long-Term Growth<br />

This crucial LCH variable is found to play a major explanatory role in every case,<br />

with t-values running as high as eight (eleven in this study). As for the magnitude<br />

<strong>of</strong> the effect, the estimates for China, <strong>of</strong> around 2 percentage points increase<br />

in S/Y per 1-percent long-term growth, or a bit larger for the second period, agree<br />

quite well with those <strong>of</strong> Cross I—a little below two when growth is approximated

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!